
Rural Housing Quality as an Indicator of Consumption Sustainability
Abhiroop Mukhopadhyay, Indira Rajaraman
An exogenously defined poverty line yields poverty headcounts between any two points in time that are a net outcome of the two-way traffic into and out of poverty. This paper argues that, for the rural Indian context, where housing is too lumpy and illiquid to be used for consumption smoothing, transitions in housing quality in cross-sectional data sets can provide revealed evidence of household perceptions of downside risk to their current consumption levels. Using the two most recent National Sample Survey housing surveys (the 58th round for 2002 and the 65th round for 2008-09), composite housing quality classifications are unbundled, and binary wall quality is selected from cross-quartile behaviour as the feature most responsive to rising household consumption levels. In both rounds, the incremental move to better quality declines beyond the consumption level at which half of all households are in better quality structures. The threshold consumption level at which this happens was lower in 2008-09 than in 2002 and reflects an improvement in housing conditions over the period. However, this effective saturation of the demand for the most basic element of better housing, much before actual saturation, provides a quantitative measure of the percentage of households even in the topmost quartile that fears downside consumption risk.
The research for this paper was funded by the Planning and Policy Research Unit, Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi, under the project titled “Finding a Tracking Identifier for Poverty”.
Abhiroop Mukhopadhyay (abhiroop@isid.ac.in) is at the Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi. The work on this paper was done while he was Sir Ratan Tata Senior Fellow at the Institute of Economic Growth, Delhi. Indira Rajaraman (indira_raja@yahoo.com) is Honorary Visiting Professor, Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi.
1 Introduction
P
Very early results in the literature on rural poverty show that there is yearly fluctuation around any poverty trend, as a result of the exogenous weather factor in rain-dependent agriculture (Ahluwalia 1978). Non-synchronous shocks across the 15 agro-climatic regions in the land mass of India add a further regional netting out across regions, so that such yearly movements in the national headcount will be the net outcome of movements into poverty in regions hit by adverse external shocks, and movements out of poverty in regions that experienced a good agricultural year. These exogenous shocks by definition affect contiguous groupings of households, but there will also be idiosyncratic shocks specific to the household (for example, shocks to health). Consumption smoothing in the face of income variability, whether idiosyncratic or otherwise, is possible if there is a financial market offering liquidity against asset collateral. Housing is the major durable asset owned by households, but in rural India in particular, it differs from all other assets in that it is not readily encashable. Housing is physically rooted in its location, and unless there is a suffi cient flow of population, as would be the case in an urban setting, it has no collateral value.
Housing varies by quality, and therefore transitions in housing quality are potentially useful markers of the confi dence of a household in its future income stream. Higher quality housing should normally exhibit income elasticity, and show a rise with income (or consumption) level, constrained at all times by the illiquidity of the asset acquired, in the event of downside income risk. Cross-sectional data on housing quality in principle therefore offer the prospect of revealing the income (or consumption) level at which confidence in staving off downside risk for the lumpy and irreversible move to be made is sufficiently widespread that there is saturation in terms of
Economic & Political Weekly
EPW
SPECIAL ARTICLE
transition to the higher quality level. At this point, the marginal coefficient for transition to higher quality housing, in response to changes in income, should begin to decline, relative to lower levels of income.
Ideally, panel data on the same set of sample households over time can reveal whether there are any downward movements of a particular household from higher to lower housing quality, contrary to the assumption made here that the key feature of housing, as distinct from other movable consumer durables, like bicycles or domestic gadgets like fans, is its irreversibility. If the assumption holds, the further corollary is that the quality of housing is an imprint of its prior consumption confidence, possibly unrelated to the actual consumption level recorded at the time of survey.
Recent work using nationwide panel data (Krishna and Shariff 2011) examine similar issues of transition into and escape from poverty. However, in their case they look at long run poverty transitions from 1993-94 to 2004-05 and model the role of household correlates. While such data are always preferable, they are sporadic. Most national level data sets that are more periodic in nature are cross sectional, such as those collected by the National Sample Survey Offi ce (NSSO).
This paper points out a unique way to look at poverty; one that endogenises household expectations of risk and future income. Accordingly, this paper examines the evidence on rural housing from two recent NSS surveys of housing, to understand housing quality transitions across the per capita consumption spectrum, divided into four quartiles.
Section 2 of the paper describes the data used from the housing surveys in the 58th round, which was canvassed over the period July to December 2002 (in effect, a half-round), and the 65th round, which covered the period July 2008 to June 2009. NSS housing surveys collect very detailed information on all aspects of housing, with the consumption level of the household recorded as part of the ancillary information on the sample household.2 Although the two housing rounds cover both rural and urban sectors, this paper is confined to the rural sector. In urban India, a bundled indicator of housing quality and location may show a more systematic relationship with consumption or income levels than housing quality alone.
Section 3 describes the method used to locate the consumption quartile in which, from the evidence of marginal probabilities of transition from lower to higher quality housing, the demand for higher housing begins to get saturated. Therefore, the residual percentage of households in the upper quartiles who have not improved their housing yields an initial handle on the percentage not sufficiently sure of their location at that consumption level to embed themselves irreversibly in higher quality housing.
An unresolved issue with rural housing is the degree to which observed data may have been affected by rural housing interventions, such as the Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY). The IAY first started as a sub-scheme of the Rural Labour Employment Guarantee Scheme in 1985-86, and became an independent scheme in 1996.3 Since both our rounds are from much later period, they are equally affected by this scheme. Therefore one can make the case that the effect of the scheme is netted out when comparing 2002 to 2008-09. However, given that IAY has seen increased funding in recent years, one could still make the case that recent improvements in housing are a result of IAY. Since IAY is targeted at the below the poverty line (BPL) population, it is clear that this will cause an increase in the number of poor people with pucca houses. However, this is unlikely to affect the turning point in the marginal probabilities of transitions in quality of housing which take place at quartiles of consumption expenditure much higher than the poverty line.
2 Data and Methods
The NSS housing surveys collect information on various aspects of the structure in which the sample household resides. Of all the features of housing quality on which information is collected, including the number of rooms, and access to water and sanitation, the most readily observed features are the type of wall and roof. The wall and roof are each classified in one of nine mutually exclusive categories. Table 1 shows that categories 1-4 in respect of each are classified as kutcha (impermanent), and 5-9 as pucca (permanent).
Table 1: Rural Housing Categories by Type
Categories for Wall and Roof
1-4 | Bamboo/reeds (1); mud/mud bricks (2); canvas/ | ||
---|---|---|---|
cloth (3); other kutcha (4) | |||
5 | Timber (wall); tiles/slate (roof) | ||
6-9 | Burnt bricks/stone (6); metal sheets (7); cement | ||
with brick or concrete (8); other pucca (9) | |||
Composite Standard Classification | Kutcha (%) | Semi-Pucca (%) | Pucca (%) |
1993 (49th round) | 31.7 | 36.0 | 32.3 |
2002 (58th round) | 21.3 | 30.3 | 48.4 |
2008-09 (65th round) | 17.0 | 27.6 | 55.4 |
Composite alt classification | |||
2002 (58th round) | 21.3 | 42.8 | 35.9 |
The standard composite classification of structures into kutcha (both wall and roof 1-4) and pucca (both wall and roof 5-9) carried a residual semi-pucca category with combinations of pucca walls (5-9) and kutcha roofs (1-4), as also structures with kutcha walls and pucca roofs. An alternate composite in the 58th round assigned tiled roofs (category 5) to the semi-pucca category, so that a pucca structure required roof categories 6-9. The estimates for that round were regenerated to be comparable with the 49th and 65th rounds. Source:NSSO reports on Housing (2002 and 2008-09).
A composite classification of the quality of the house as a whole is provided in the offi cial NSS reports on the housing surveys, into kutcha housing (both wall and roof in categories 1-4), pucca housing (wall and roof in categories 5-9), and a residual semi-pucca category, in which wall and roof do not fall in the same numbered range of categories. Table 1 shows the data from the NSS reports on three rounds, the 49th (January to December 1993), 58th (July-December 2002) and the 65th round (July 2008 to June 2009).
The figures suggest a substantial improvement in housing condition in rural areas, with kutcha structures down from 31% to 17% over the 15 years from 1993 to 2008-09, and pucca structures up from 32% to 55%. When, as happened in the 58th round (2002), roofs of tile/slate are assigned out of the pucca category into the semi-pucca, the share of pucca structures goes down substantially from 48% to 36%.
Clearly, the housing quality descriptives need to be unbundled, and this is generated from the primary data for the latest
march 24, 2012 vol xlvii no 12
SPECIAL ARTICLE
round in 2008-09 in Table 2, by monthly per capita consumption (MPCE) quartile. These are quartiles of households, not of the total population, and are formed after weighting each sample household by the household multiplier supplied by the NSS. The official poverty line for 2004-05 was a monthly per capita consumption of Rs 356.35. The equivalent at 2002-03 prices works out to Rs 334. All consumption figures for 2008-09 in the table are shown at 2002-03 prices. The poverty line at 2002-03 prices is just a little above the cut-off for quartile 1.
Table 2: Wall and Roof Quality by Quartile (% share; 2008-09)
Quartile 1 | Quartile 2 | Quartile 3 | Quartile 4 | Total | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean MPCE, 2002 prices (Rs) | 258.34 | 379.63 | 507.68 | 907.42 | 510.06 |
Max MPCE, 2002 prices (Rs) | 326.57 | 433.87 | 594.82 29,678.62 29,678.62 | ||
Wall quality percentages | |||||
K-wall, K-roof | 23 | 19 | 16 | 9 | 17 |
K-wall, tiled roof | 22 | 15 | 12 | 8 | 14 |
K-wall, non-tile pucca roof | 9 | 9 | 9 | 6 | 9 |
K-wall subtotal | 54 | 43 | 37 | 23 | 40 |
K-wall, cumulative | 54 | 49 | 45 | 40 | |
P-wall, kutcha roof | 6 | 5 | 4 | 3 | 4 |
P-wall, tiled roof | 9 | 11 | 12 | 12 | 11 |
P-wall, non-tile pucca roof | 31 | 41 | 46 | 62 | 45 |
P-wall subtotal | 46 | 57 | 62 | 77 | 60 |
P-wall, cumulative | 46 | 51 | 55 | 60 | |
Total | 100 | 100 | 100 | 100 | 100 |
Roof quality percentages | |||||
K-roof | 29 | 24 | 20 | 12 | 22 |
Tiled roof | 31 | 26 | 24 | 20 | 25 |
Non-tile pucca roof | 40 | 50 | 56 | 68 | 53 |
Total | 100 | 100 | 100 | 100 | 100 |
Household quartiles are marked off by rupees per capita monthly consumption expenditure (MPCE) at 2002 prices, deflated by the Consumer Price Index for Agricultural Labourers. All figures are obtained after weighting by household weights, not population weights. Source: Authors’ calculations from the 65th round housing survey of the NSS, covering the period July 2008 to June 2009.
Three features of the quartile wise data are especially noteworthy. First, the percentage share of the kutcha wall-kutcha roof (k-wall, k-roof) combination declines sharply across quartiles, but so does the share of structures with a tiled or other pucca roof overlaid on a kutcha wall. Structures with kutcha walls, aggregating across roof types, decline steadily from 54% of total structures in quartile 1 to 23% in quartile 4. The decline in share from quartile 1, to 43% in quartile 2, is particularly sharp. This cross-quartile behaviour, in particular the substantial movement out of kutcha walls going from quartile 1 to quartile 2, reveal kutcha walls to be inferior to pucca walls. The overall share across all quartiles of this (revealed inferior) type of structure with kutcha walls is 40%, much higher than the 17% share of the composite kutcha structure.
The second noteworthy feature, is that when structures are aggregated by roof type, the share of structures with a kutcha roof is much lower even in the lowest quartile, at 29%, and declines much less sharply going into quartile 2. The overall share across all quartiles of structures with a kutcha roof is only 22%. Kutcha wall structures are more likely to have a non-kutcha roof of tile, or better than tile, even in the lowest quartile. Also, once the irreversible transition to a pucca wall is made, there is a small stable per cent of structures staying with a kutcha roof cover pending the pucca roof. Thus, the
Economic & Political Weekly
EPW
share of structures with a kutcha roof, irrespective of wall quality, is much flatter across quartiles as compared to kutcha walls.
Third, the spread between the quartiles in housing quality is much narrower than the spread in mpce, shown in the table. The mean mpce in the upper quartile is 3.5 times that in the lowest quartile, but the percentage share with pucca walls rises from 46% in the lowest to only 77% in the highest quartile. (The consumption expenditure figures in the table are all at 2002-03 prices.) Even in the uppermost quartile, the share of households with kutcha walls is as high as 23%. This is somewhat startling. Likewise the share of households with pucca walls in the lowest quartile, at 46%, is also much higher than might be expected. The shares by roof quality are even fl atter across quartiles.
These descriptives point to wall, rather than roof quality, as the feature of housing quality that rises most sharply with household consumption levels. The incremental change in wall quality is sharpest between quartiles 3 and 4.
The issue of the high share of pucca walls in the lowest quartile remains puzzling. There are two possible explanations. One is that this is the result of interventions such as the IAY. A second possibility is that this is the result of movement downward into poverty of households that had earlier been able to upgrade wall quality.
Table 3 shows quartile specific housing shares in the 58th round at the quartile cut-offs corresponding to those in the 65th round (for comparability across the rounds, but as shown in Table 3, the cut-offs yield quartiles approximately here as well). Here again, the pucca wall share in the lowest group is 38%, rising to 71% in the highest group. It seems implausible that so large a share in the lowest quartile between NSS rounds would be a result of downward movement of households on the consumption scale, so the high percentages among the lowest group has to be a result of policy interventions among designated poverty groups. This if anything only heightens
Table 3: Wall and Roof Quality by Quartile (% Share), 2002, using Quartile Cut-offs from the 65th Round (2008-09)
Quantile 1 | Quantile 2 | Quantile 3 | Quantile 4 | Total | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean MPCE, 2002 prices (Rs) | 245.57 | 380.01 | 500.08 | 843.98 | 492.63 |
Max MPCE, 2002 prices (Rs) | 326.57 | 433.87 | 594.82 | 8,000.00 8,000.00 | |
Per cent households | |||||
at 65th round quartile cut-offs | 25.31 | 26.62 | 22.88 | 25.2 | |
Housing quality percentages | |||||
K-wall, K-roof | 31 | 24 | 19 | 11 | 21 |
K-wall, tiled roof | 24 | 21 | 17 | 12 | 19 |
K-wall, non-tile pucca roof | 7 | 9 | 8 | 6 | 7 |
K-wall subtotal | 62 | 54 | 44 | 29 | 47 |
K-wall, cumulative | 62 | 58 | 53 | 47 | |
P-wall, kutcha roof | 4 | 5 | 5 | 3 | 4 |
P-wall, tiled roof | 11 | 11 | 13 | 16 | 13 |
P-wall, non-tile pucca roof | 23 | 31 | 38 | 52 | 36 |
P-wall subtotal | 38 | 47 | 56 | 71 | 53 |
P-wall, cumulative | 38 | 42 | 47 | 53 | |
Total | 100 | 100 | 100 | 100 | 100 |
Household quantiles are marked off using the same cut-offs which marked off household quartiles in the 65th round. Source: Authors’ calculations from the 58th round housing survey of the NSS, covering the period July to December 2002.
SPECIAL ARTICLE
the puzzle over the lack of full coverage in the highest quartile groups of a permanent wall, the most basic dimension of housing quality.
Comparing across the rounds, 51% of the lowest two quartiles in 2008-09 had pucca walls, as opposed to only 42% of those at equivalent consumption levels in 2002. Cumulatively, the bottom three quartiles in 2008-09 had 55%, higher than the overall pucca wall share of 53% in 2002. If the move to pucca walls is taken as irreversible, then the rise in the share of pucca wall structures is plausible even in classes defi ned by equivalent consumption levels, since the change would refl ect the addition to the stock on account of households which experienced an improvement in mpce within the same cut-off markers.
3 Results
Table 4 shows the results from a probit specifi cation estimating the probability of transition to a pucca wall estimated separately for each quartile, with controls for NSS state-regions. (75 state regions as defined in the 58th round – these allow for even more flexibility than considering only agro-climatic zones which would require coarser partitions of the country.) The quartile-specific estimation allows the estimation of marginal coefficients at the average of ranges of per capita consumption, specified by (in this case, equal numbers of) households falling in the range.4
Table 4: Marginal Coefficients for Probability of Transition to a Pucca Wall, by MPCE Quartiles for the 65th and 58th Rounds (Rural)
Unit Quartile 1 Quartile 2 Quartile 3 Quartile 4
Average marginal effect of one rupee increase in MPCE 2008-09 Exp (-4) 2.982 6.721 2.920 0.933
2002 Exp (-4) 1.630 6.191 8.231 1.609
Average marginal effect of one
rupee increase in total hh con exp
2008-09 Exp (-4) 0.301 1.324 1.328 0.168
2002 Exp (-4) -0.581 0.610 1.184 0.432
The nominal consumption levels in the 65th round were deflated to 58th round prices. Quartiles were formed with respect to consumption levels in the 65th round and the same absolute MPCE quartile cut-offs were used for the 58th round as well (see Table 3). Source: Authors’ calculations from the 58th (2002) and 65th (2008-09) round housing surveys of the NSS.
We test the following specification across n sample households in each survey, and the 75 state-regions, as defined in the 58th round, in which the sample household falls:
74
Pr(yi = 1) = ) (D +E. xi + 6Gj . Dsj);i = l,...,n
j=1
where yi i is the binary dependent variable which takes a value of one if the household dwelling has a pucca wall, and zero if it does not, for the ith sample household. xi is the monthly per capita consumption of household i and Dsj is a dummy variable for the NSS region j, and is a catch-all residual capturing the agro-climatic and economic environment in which the sample household falls.
The marginal probability of transition to a pucca wall, estimated at the average of each quartile, for every rupee increase in mpce, rises from quartile 1 to quartile 2 in 2008-09, but then declines in quartile 3 and then further in quartile 4. For durables like a pucca wall, the decline in the marginal coeffi cient would normally be indicative of saturation. However, at the start of the consumption range defining quartile 3, half of households cumulating across the bottom two quartiles were without a pucca wall. Within quartile 3, 37% of households were without a pucca wall. The further sharp decline in the marginal coeffi cient in quartile 4 coexists with 23% of households in that quartile without a pucca wall.
The marginal coefficients for the 58th round segments, are estimated at the quartile cut-offs of the 65th round so as to be for comparable consumption ranges. These approximate very roughly to quartiles of the 58th round itself. The marginal coefficients for this round show a decline only in quartile 4. This implies that over time, there has either been an improvement in housing or households are now less secure about their future incomes. Since the proportion of households with pucca walls has risen in every quartile, it is more likely that our results reflects an improvement in housing quality.
The estimates were also run for total household expenditure rather than mpce, within the same quartiles defi ned by mpce, to check for whether the pattern of transitions might change with total expenditure, which incorporates household size. The results are broadly similar, except that in 2008-09, the marginal coefficient rises slightly in quartile 3 relative to quartile 2, before declining in quartile 4. The negative coeffi cient in the lowest quartile for 2002, is clearly because of household size in this quartile increasing more than proportionately with household total expenditure. This result in particular suggests that mpce is the better indicator of transitions in housing quality. If the move to a pucca wall, as a decision not easily reversed or encashable, is taken as an indicator of confi dence in the sustainability of current consumption levels, these results in conjunction with the stock descriptives in Tables 2 and 3 suggest some structural similarities in terms of confi dence about downside consumption risk in 2008-09 relative to 2002. The marginal coefficients decline in 2002 in quartile 4, at a cumulative starting stock of 47% pucca walls, and in 2008-09 at quartile 3, at a starting cumulative stock of 51%. Beyond the consumption level at which about half of all households have a pucca wall, the incremental move to a pucca wall declines.
The coefficient for the lowest quartile is much higher in 2008-09 than in 2002, which once again heightens the puzzle over IAY interventions for households BPL. If that intervention had operated at the lowest end of the quartile, it should in principle have flattened the slope. But instead the marginal coeffi cient has risen in 2008-09 for this quartile relative to 2002 quite sharply, suggesting that the benefits of this programme accrue to those at the top end of the poverty range.
Conclusions
By the latest rural housing survey for 2008-09 from the 65th round of the NSS, structures classified as kutcha (a kutcha roof on a kutcha wall) account for 17% of all structures. However, when structures are not assigned a unique composite classification, and are unbundled by type of wall and roof, the share of rural structures with a kutcha wall (of mud or bamboo), at
march 24, 2012 vol xlvii no 12
SPECIAL ARTICLE
40%, is far higher. The overlay of a tile or metal sheet roof on a kutcha wall accounts for the difference. Structures with a kutcha wall, aggregating across roof types, show a sharp decline in share across consumption quartiles in both the 65th round, and the 58th round housing survey for 2002. Pucca walls show a corresponding increase in share, revealing these to be clearly preferred, with the incremental shift in wall quality sharpest between quartiles 3 and 4. By contrast, the share of structures with a tile or other pucca roof, irrespective of wall quality, is much flatter across quartiles. These descriptives point to wall, rather than roof, type as the best indicator of improvements in housing quality as households move up the consumption scale.
A transition to a pucca wall is also irreversible, because it is physically rooted in its location, and unless there is a suffi cient flow of population, as would be the case in an urban setting, has no collateral value. Following from this, the transition of a household to a pucca wall will be constrained by household assessments of the sustainability of their current consumption levels. These estimates of sustainability could differ for different ranges of household mpce. Also, at higher ranges of mpce, the probability of transition will be constrained by the received stock of structures that have already made the transition.
The paper therefore estimates, separately for each consumption quartile, the marginal probabilities of transition to pucca walls, for every rise of one rupee in mpce, with dummy variables controlling for the state-region in which the household is located. The marginal probability of transition from a kutcha to a pucca wall in 2008-09 rises from quartile 1 to quartile 2, but then declines in quartile 3 and then further in quartile 4. For durables like a pucca wall, the decline in the marginal coefficient would normally be indicative of saturation. However, at the start of the consumption range defi ning quartile 3, 51% of households cumulating across the lowest two quartiles were without a pucca wall. Within quartile 3 alone, 37% of households were without a pucca wall. The further sharp decline in the marginal coefficient in quartile 4 coexists with 23% of households in that quartile without a pucca wall. This effective saturation of the demand for the most basic element of better housing, much before actual saturation, provides a quantitative measure of the per cent of households even in the topmost quartile that fears downside consumption risk.
In 2002, the marginal coefficient declines only in quartile 4 (using the same real mpce cut-offs as 2008-09), at a cumulative stock of 47% pucca walls. Since the decline in the marginal coefficient occurs in 2008-09 at quartile 3, at a cumulative stock of 51% with pucca walls, the incremental move to a pucca wall declines in both years beyond the real consumption level at which about half of all households have a pucca wall, where that consumption level itself is lower in 2008-09 than in 2002. If the move to a pucca wall, as a decision not easily reversed or encashable, is taken as an indicator of confi dence in the sustainability of current consumption levels, these results suggest that the structural parameters defining fear of downside consumption risk have not changed appreciably during this period, despite the rise in current mpce between the two survey years. The decline in the share of kutcha wall structures from 47% in 2002 to 40% in 2008-09, and the corresponding rise in pucca wall structures from 53% to 60%, does mark a slight improvement in the rural housing stock between 2002 and 2008-09.
The spread between the quartiles in housing quality is much narrower than the spread in per capita consumption levels. The mean mpce in the upper quartile in 2008-09 is 3.5 times that in the lowest quartile, but the percentage share with puccaa walls is 77% in the highest quartile, as against 46% in the lowest quartile.
Finally, the high share of structures with pucca walls at the lowest quartile is possibly a result of the rural housing scheme (IAY). The marginal coefficient for the probability of transiting to a pucca wall in the lowest quartile is much higher in 2008-09 than in 2002. If that intervention had operated at the lowest end of the quartile, it should in principle have fl attened the slope. But instead the marginal coefficient has risen in 2008-09 for this quartile relative to 2002 quite sharply, suggesting that the benefits of this programme accrue to those at the top end of the poverty range.
Notes
1 Himanshu (2010) provides a detailed description of these alternative poverty lines.
2 The samples drawn for the consumption and housing surveys in any round are different so that no link is possible between the two.
3 http://rural.nic.in/iaygd2.html
4 Alternatively, we could have considered a quadratic specification in terms of per capita consumption but this would impose a parametric shape to our relationship.
References
Ahluwalia, M (1978): “Rural Poverty and Agriculture Performance in India”, Journal of Development Studies, Vol 14, Issue No 2, April, pp 298-323.
Himanshu (2010): “Towards New Poverty Lines for India”, Economic Political Weekly, Vol 45, Issue No 1, 2-8 January, pp 38-48.
Krishna, A and A Shariff (2011): “The Irrelevance of
Economic Political Weekly march 24, 2012

National Strategies? Rural Poverty Dynamics Housing Stock and Constructions”, Report in States and Regions of India, 1993-2005”, No 488, March. World Development. – (2010): “Housing Condition and Amenities in
NSSO (2004): “Housing Condition in India, 2002: India: 2008-09”, Report No 535, November.
For the Attention of Subscribers and Subscription Agencies Outside India
It has come to our notice that a large number of subscriptions to the EPW from outside the country together with the subscription payments sent to supposed subscription agents in India have not been forwarded to us.
We wish to point out to subscribers and subscription agencies outside India that all foreign subscriptions, t ogether with the appropriate remittances, must be forwarded to us and not to unauthorised third parties in India.
We take no responsibility whatsoever in respect of subscriptions not registered with us. MANAGER
vol xlvii no 12