COMMENTARY
Goods and Services Tax: Some Progress towards Clarity
M Govinda Rao
the recent reforms to introduce the VAT at both the central and state levels, a considerable amount of cascading continues. The high threshold and large list of exemptions in the central value added tax (CENVAT) and non-inclusion of a number of services in the service tax do not allow
The first discussion paper on Goods and Services Tax released by the Empowered Committee is an important step in signalling the consensus and commitment to harmonise the indirect taxes levied by the states and the centre and in traversing some distance in clarifying the design and implementation aspects of the new tax regime. The efforts of the EC must be complimented for building a consensus on many a contentious issue in the process of evolving the GST in the country. However, much more remains to be done, many of the design and implementation issues are yet to be negotiated and settled and it would take considerable time and effort before they are finalised.
M Govinda Rao (mgr@nipfp.org.in) is at the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi.
T
At the outset, it is necessary to note that the GST will not be a new tax. It is only a further improvement over the prevailing consumption tax systems at the centre and states. At present, there is a value added tax (VAT) at the manufacturing stage on goods and a separate tax on selected services at the centre and an intra-state VAT up to the retail stage at the state level. R eforms over the years have gone some distance in reducing cascading by providing for input tax credit. Nevertheless, the tax bases at both the central and state l evels are narrow, making the VAT chain incomplete with significant cascading e lements, remaining at both the levels.
At the centre, the tax base does not include value added at stages subsequent to manufacturing and leaves out a number of services. The states, on the other hand, cannot tax services except the ones that are specified in the state list under the Seventh Schedule to the Constitution such as the entertainment tax, electricity duty and passengers and goods tax. In spite of
december 19, 2009
the input tax credit chain to be completed and this causes considerable distortions due to cascading elements in the tax. S imilarly, at the state level, non-inclusion of services prevents completion of the chain as goods are used in providing services and services enter into the manufacture of goods, not taxing services prevents providing input tax credit to them and in the process some cascading has continued even after VAT was introduced.
The introduction of GST is expected to expand the base of the tax and reduce distor tions by eliminating input taxes further. Thus, GST is not a new tax, but s imply a more comprehensive VAT on goods and services. The discussion paper devotes considerable space to clarifying this.
There are at least three reasons why the first discussion paper put out by the EC must be welcomed. First, it reiterates the commitment to reform the consumption tax system towards evolving the GST. Second, it helps to initiate discussion on the new tax regime with various stakeholders especially, various business groups, tax experts and people at large. Finally, the discussion paper goes some distance in clarifying the design and i mplementation aspects of the new tax r egime. Although this is short of expectations, the process initiated is important and hopefully there will be more discussion papers as the reform process advances and various issues of the new tax r egime get finalised.
Salient Features
The discussion paper details the basic features of the GST structure and implementation aspects. Of course, some of the d etails were already known and a few
vol xliv no 51
EPW
COMMENTARY
the state level (SGST). Each taxpayer will be allotted a PAN-linked taxpayer identification number with 13/15 digits. The dual GST will be implemented through multiple statutes – one for CGST and one for each SGST. The new tax system would have a broader base to include wholesale and retail trade in the case of the CGST and all services in the case of the SGST. The basic features of the acts, including definitions and the classification system, are expected to be uniform among the various state statutes “as far as practicable”. To the e xtent feasible, a uniform procedure will be followed for the collection of both CGST and SGST.
(ii) There will be separate tax administrations at the centre and in the states. I nput tax paid on CGST will be credited against the output tax on CGST and those on SGST will be credited against the SGST. Cross-utilisation of input tax credit (ITC) between CGST and SGST will not be allowed. Thus, there will be some cascading in the tax system.
(iii) The CGST will have a threshold of Rs 1.5 crore. The threshold for the SGST is proposed at Rs 10 lakh, which would be uniform for all states and union territories. A simplified tax at 0.5% of the turnover will be levied for dealers with a turnover up to Rs 50 lakh. In the case of CGST, however, the threshold is proposed to be kept at Rs 1.5 crore in the interest of small traders and small-scale industries.
Economic & Political Weekly
EPW
p ractice in addition to levying state excise duties. However, tobacco products will be included in the SGST with proper input tax credit. In addition, the central government can levy excise duty.
(vi) The prevailing practice in regard to the taxation of crude, motor spirit (including aviation turbine fuel) and high speed diesel (HSD) will continue and these items will be kept outside the SGST and the tax would continue to be levied on these products with a floor rate. A final view on whether natural gas should also be kept outside the SGST will be taken after further deliberations by the EC. Thus, cascading on account of this will continue. Since, on an average, states receive over 30% of sales tax revenue from these products and as these are largely marketed through the public sector oil marketing companies, a dministering the tax on these items is easy and compliance of the tax is high. Surely, the states have decided to live with distortions in the interest of revenue.
(vii) States will have concurrent powers to levy the tax on services. In the case of services of an inter-state benefit span, if these are intermediate services, a model of integrated GST (IGST) has been introduced to ensure seamless trade while making the system destination-based. However, if these are in the nature of final consumption, it is not clear how the revenues will be apportioned between the states where the service is produced, transacted and consumed.
(viii) The important feature of the GST scheme is the mechanism to ensure a common market. To ensure seamless trade across the country, the discussion paper puts forth the IGST model. In this model, the inter-state seller of goods and services will pay the IGST, which will be equal to the total of CGST and SGST a fter taking credit of the input taxes to the central agency, to be created especially to administer the IGST. The exporting state credits the input tax revenue to the account of the importing state. The central agency will credit the SGST c ollected by it to the account of the i mporting State and the importing dealer will collect the SGST on his sales after taking credit of the tax already paid and the chain will continue. The process not only ensures seamless trade and
vol xliv no 51
u ninterrupted ITC chain but also enables the levy to be destination-based.
Although the discussion paper goes to a considerable distance to provide conceptual clarity on a number of issues the available information on the proposed GST system brings out some inadequacies. It is well known that in all federal fiscal systems, tax assignment has to strike a compromise b etween fiscal autonomy and tax harmony and some inefficiency may have to be a ccepted. However, there are others which hopefully, after due consideration will be ironed out.
Shortcomings
Some of the important shortcomings of the proposed GST are summarised in the following.
COMMENTARY
it does not include stamp duties and registration fees. Furthermore, entertainment tax, if levied by local bodies (Kerala) will continue. Thus, while the proposal goes a long way in unifying multiple taxes, it still leaves out some taxes. Indeed, it is important to ensure that revenue sources of local bodies are protected. The more r ational course would be to add an additional percentage point to SGST as a local levy and distribute the proceeds to urban and rural local governments based on their consumption shares. Maharashtra, the only state in which municipal corporations are allowed to levy octroi too can abolish it.
if at all, is on the basis of income elasticity of demand. As mentioned above, even this need not ensure overall equity in the general equilibrium sense; but tax design is less of a science and more of exercising socio-political judgments. Since under GST input tax will get the credit, there is no need to maintain a special treatment for “goods of special importance”.
Challenges in Implementation
While the discussion paper traverses some distance in providing clarification on the new tax regime, and this is particularly true of the treatment of inter-state transactions, there are many other areas which
december 19, 2009
are still unclear. Furthermore, much more work needs to be done before a clear picture of the new tax system emerges. Some of the challenges to be faced in implementing the GST regime are summarised in the following:
vol xliv no 51
EPW
COMMENTARY
and in each of the states. This is necessary not only to arrive at convergence on the tax rates to be levied but also to negotiate and finalise the compensation plan. In any case, to ensure success of the tax and evoke high degree of compliance, it would be useful to keep the rates low, but that would require the centre taking a lead in assuring the comfort of insurance against fall in revenue at least for the next three years by promising to compensate the states for the revenue loss.
It may be recalled that when Thailand introduced VAT in January 1992, the estimated revenue neutral rate was 10%, but they decided to levy the tax at 7%. Not only did they realise the full revenue at this lower rate, but their income tax revenue too went up by 25%! During the Asian financial crisis they had to increase the rate to 10% under International Monetary Fund pressure, but once they came out of the crisis, they reverted back to 7%!
Eventually, the success of GST will depend on improved compliance, higher productivity growth leading to faster economic growth and buoyant revenues. Hopefully, both the centre and states will realise this and keep the rates low.
Economic & Political Weekly
EPW
financial intermediation, which is a genuine development activity, from financial services. In some cases, it is possible to identify the service charges and in others it is inextricably mixed up with profits. In the case of general insurance, for example, it is inappropriate to consider the premium paid as is being done now, for this does not constitute the service. It is necessary to net this out with the settlement of claims to arrive at the right base.
vol xliv no 51
bargaining and dispute resolution mechanism is important to ensure compliance of the agreements by all the parties concerned. So far, the EC has done a commendable task of forging consensus on many a contentious issue. Never theless, the institution is informal and needs to be placed on a much more secure footing.
Conclusions
Reforming the consumption tax system in an intergovernmental context is an extremely difficult issue. In a globalising environment, it is necessary that the tax system generates sufficient revenues to provide efficient infrastructure. However, these revenues should be raised by minimising the three costs – the cost of collection, the cost of compliance and the economic costs arising from distortions. In an intergovernmental context, all these have to be achieved while ensuring fiscal autonomy to subnational jurisdictions. A completely harmonised tax system which is very much desired by the businesses can be achieved only at the cost of fiscal autonomy of the states. Complete harmonisation is equivalent to uniformity and this takes away the powers of the states to vary their public services and taxes.
In Indian fiscal federalism, uniformity is being achieved by building consensus among the states by the EC. Nevertheless, this will reduce the ability of the states to vary the levels of public services and taxes. This is the trade off exercised between fiscal autonomy and tax disharmony,
Thus, the first discussion paper of EC reaffirms the commitment to shift to a GST and helps to understand the broad contours of the tax. However, much more remains to be done and many of the design and implementation issues are yet to be negotiated and settled and it would take considerable time and effort before they are finalised. The opportunity should be used also to overcome some of the shortcomings in the existing design of VAT.
It is important to prepare well before switching over to the new system to ensure sound fundamentals to the new tax system. The efforts of the EC must be complimented in weeding through the most difficult terrain of building a consensus on many a contentious issue in the process of evolving the GST in the country.