Regional Structures, Growth and Convergence of Income in Maharashtra
In the evolution of spatial economies, it may so happen that regions may converge at one “spatial scale” but can diverge at another scale, or there may be marked presence of “convergence clubs”. This paper analyses sectoral and aggregate per capita incomes in Maharashtra over the period 1993-94 to 2002-03. In contrast to the trend of divergence at the interstate level, the regional economies in Maharashtra are converging, though with significant differences in the rates of convergence across various sectors and regions. Marathwada and Vidarbha, with weak industrial sectors, have been the most underdeveloped regions in the state over the years. The study also highlights the impact of “spatial spillovers” on regional patterns of economic development in the state and its policy implications.
ABDUL SHABAN
I Introduction
M
Notwithstanding the overall higher economic growth and development in the state, all is not well with its economy as obsession with economic growth and generation of wealth has led to the relative neglect of distributional aspects. It has frequently been stated that if Greater Mumbai, and Pune division are taken out, the rest of Maharashtra would not be better than the ‘BIMARU’ states. Demand for a separate state of Vidarbha on the basis of its low development and the demand for more allocation of financial resources for the development of Marathwada can be seen in the above context.
The present paper attempts to examine the trends in regional inequality in sectoral as well as aggregate per capita income in Maharashtra. More specifically, it attempts, (1) to discern the regional structures of income and the composition of regional income in the state of Maharashtra (regions being defined in terms of districts and groups of districts), (2) to examine inter-regional and inter-sectoral differences in the growth rate of income, (3) to analyse the level and trends in regional income inequality, (4) to explore the relationship between trends in spatial associations and regional inequality, and (5) to throwlight on regional convergence and the spatial spillover process in the state.
The paper is divided into six sections. Section II deals with data and methodology used in the study. It also briefly discusses the limitation of conventional econometric methods in analysing spatial data and how spatial econometric methods have an advantage over the conventional methods. Sectoral composition of regional incomes and their growth are examined in Section III, and an analysis of regional inequality in income is presented in Section IV. Section IV also highlights the relationship between trend in regional inequality and spatial associations. Convergence of regional income and the spatial spillover process through simulation are examined in Section V. The last section presents a summary and conclusions.
II Data and Methodology
The directorate of economics and statistics, government of Maharashtra, Mumbai has compiled district-wise ‘Net Domestic Product’ for the state from 1993-94 onwards. The latest year for which the data are available is 2002-03. This 10-year data (199394 to 2002-03) for the districts in the state have been used in the present study. There were 30 districts in the state in 199394, and since then five new districts have been created. In order to maintain comparability of the data of spatial units, the data for newly created districts have been clubbed with their parent districts. To analyse regional inequality and convergence, various statistical methods, besides “different ratios and proportions”, have been used. Some of these methods are briefly presented below:
Measures of Regional Inequality
To measure district level inequality in per capita income, the Gini coefficient, Theil’s inequality index (global and decomposed), and the coefficient of variation (CV) have been used.
The Gini coefficient is derived from the Lorenz curve. There are several ways to compute the Gini coefficient for a dataset.
The present study uses the following formula to calculate the Gini coefficient (G). n
G = Σi–1 (2i – n – 1)x' i/n2 μ …(1)
Where i is the individual’s rank order number, n is the number of total individuals, xi' is the individual’s value, and μis the population average. The Gini coefficient is a full-information measure, looking at all parts of the distribution. G ranges between zero and 1: a zero shows perfect equality among regions/individuals and 1 indicates that all development is concentrated to only one region/individual. It facilitates direct comparison between two populations regardless of their sizes.
Among regional inequality measures, another preferred method is Theil’s index of inequality (T) as it allows easy decomposition of total inequality between and within regions. T is computed as follows [Rey 2001]:
n
T = Σi=1 siln(nsi) …(2) Where n is the number of regions, yi is the variable in question in regions i, and n
si = yi/Σ…(3)
i=1yi
The decomposition property of T has been exploited to investigate the extent to which global inequality is attributable to inequality “between” or “within” a regional grouping. By partitioning the n spatial observations into ωmutually exclusive and exhaustive groups, T can be decomposed as follows:
ω ω
T = Σg=1sg ln(n/ngsg) + Σg=1 Σi∈g Si,g ln (ngsi,g) …(4)
Where ng is the number of observations in group g (and Εgng = n),
n
sg = Σi=g yi,g/Σi=lyi is the share of total value of the variable y ngaccounted for by group g, and si,g = yi,g / Σi=l yi,g is region i’s share of group g’s value. The first term on the right hand side of the above equation is the “between-group” (TB) component of inequality, while the second term is the ”within-group” group (T) component of
winequality. In other words:
T = TB + T…(5)
w
In spatial context, the within-group term measures intraregional inequality, while the between-group component captures inter-regional inequality. In other words, the inter-regional term measures the distance between the mean values of the aggregate groups, while the intra-regional term measures distance between the values of units belonging to the same region.
Measure of Spatial Autocorrelation: Moran’s I
Spatial autocorrelation can be defined in terms of value similarity with locational similarity [Anselin and Bera 1998]. Positive spatial autocorrelation occurs when similar values for a variable are clustered together, and negative spatial autocorrelation appears when dissimilar values are clustered in space. Although various methods have been proposed to measure the spatial autocorrelation, the present study uses Moran’s I statistics, which is most widely used measure of spatial autocorrelation. Moran’s I is computed as follows:
nn ΣΣ wij xi xj
⎛n ⎞ i=1 j=1 I =⎜ ⎟ n
s 2
⎝ 0 ⎠Σxi
i=1 ...(6)
Where n is the number of observations, wij is the element in spatial weight matrix w corresponding to the region (i,j), the observations xi and xj are in deviation from their mean values for region i and j, respectively, and s0 is the normalising factor equal to the sum of the elements of the weight matrix, i e, s0 = ΣiΣj wij [Anselin 1992].
Different definitions of interaction between regions cause different spatial weight matrices. The study adopts the simplest but most powerful the binary contiguity matrix, where the element (i,j) of the spatial weight matrix, wij = 1 if region i and j share a border, and zero otherwise [Anselin 1992; Hanning 1990; Upton and Fingleton 1985]. When the spatial weight matrix is row standardised such that sum of each row equals 1, the expression [Lim 2003] given above simplifies to:
nn ΣΣ wij xi xji=1 j=1 I = n Σxi 2 …(7) i=1 or, in matrix notation:
x'wx
I = ——— ...(8)
x'x
Where w is a spatial weight matrix and x is vector of observed value in deviation from the mean. The value of Moran’s I ranges between -1 and +1. Negative value of Moran’s I shows negative spatial autocorrelation and vice versa. When the spatial weight matrix is row standardardised, the spatial lag value of the region is equal to the mean value of the neighbouring regions.
If regions with similar values/per capita income are clustered together, the positive spatial autocorrelation is observed, and if the arrangement of spatial units in geographic space is such that they form a check-board pattern, a negative spatial autocorrelation is the outcome. Comparing the spatial autocorrelation in per capita income for each year, the study traces the trajectory of regional dynamics and distribution patterns of income over time.
In order to have a more disaggregated view of spatial autocorrelation/association, the Moran Scatter Plot suggested by Anselin (1996), has been used to capture the local structure of spatial associations. Since the elements in the vector x in the above equation are deviations from the mean, the Morna’s I statistic is formally equivalent to the slope coefficient in the linear regression of spatial lag wx on x. With the help of the Moran scatter plot, one can decompose the global spatial association into four different quadrants, which correspond to four different kinds of local spatial associations between a region and its neighbour. These four quadrants and association types are:
Regression Analysis
A conventional “ordinary least square” (OLS) regression equation can be stated as,
y = α + βX + ε ...(9)
where y shows a vector of dependent variable, and X presents independent variables. The above equation assumes that random error terms, ε, is normally distributed with zero mean and homoscedastic variance σ2.
However, in the above equation, there are no parameters that take care of spatial effects or spatial autocorrelation in the data. The equation treats regions as “isolated islands” [Quah 1996]. It does not capture the fact that one region’s economic destiny is dependent upon those of other regions. Indeed, the evolution of each region is closely related to the evolution of, at least, neighbouring regions. We, therefore, assume that regional distribution of income is unlikely to be spatially independent and random. When models are estimated for cross-sectional data on spatial units, the lack of independence across these units can cause a serious problem of model misspecification when ignored [Anselin 1988; Lim 2003]. Three kinds of models/specifications can be used to deal with spatial dependence of observations: The spatial lag model, the spatial error model, and spatial cross-regressive1 model [Rey and Montouri 1999; Anselin 1988; Anselin and Bera 1998].
In spatial lag model, substantive spatial dependence (through spatial externalities and spillover effects) is incorporated through a spatially lagged dependent variable:
y = α + βln X + ρwy + ε ...(10)
where ρ is a scalar spatial autoregressive coefficient, wy is spatial lagged dependent variable for a spatial weight matrix w. Thus, in this model the resulting per capita income in a region is also considered to be dependent on per capita income in its neighbouring region. The ordinary least square (OLS) estimator of this model yields biased and inconsistent estimates for the coefficients due to the simultaneity between the error term and the spatially lagged variable. Therefore, alternative estimators based on maximum likelihood (ML) and instrumental variables have been suggested for the estimation to get consistent results [Anselin 1988; Anselin and Bera 1998]. The paper uses the ML estimate of this model.
The spatial error model is applied when spatial dependence is expected while working through the error process, which can result from a measurement problem [Rey and Montouri 1999]. Spatial error dependence may be interpreted as a “nuisance” in that it reflects spatial autocorrelation in measurement errors in variables that are otherwise not crucial for the model. The spatial process pertaining to the error term can be expressed as [Lim 2003; Rey and Montouri 1999]:
ε = λwε + ξ
...(11)ε = (I–λw)–1ξ
where ε is a vector error terms, λ is a spatial error coefficient. ξ is a vector of error terms, which is normally distributed with zero mean and homoscedastic variance σ2 ξ. Including the spatial autocorrelation of the error terms, the above given regression model becomes:
y = α + βX + (I -λw)–1ξ ...(12)
The OLS estimator will again give biased estimates of the parameters’ variance. Therefore, the spatial error model is estimated with ML method [Anselin 1988; Anselin and Bera 1998]. From the equation (12) it is evident that a random shock introduced into a specific district will not only affect the growth rate in that district, but through spatial transformation (I -ξW)–1, will impact the growth rate of other districts as well. The inverse operator in the transformation defines an error covariance structure that diffuses district specific shocks not only to the district’s neighbours but throughout the system [Rey and Montouri 1999].
Geographically Weighted Regression:Spatially Drifting β-coefficients
When the usual regression methods are applied to spatial data, it is assumed that there exists a stationary spatial process. However, spatial data are seldom stationary. When spatial non-stationarity exists, the same stimulus or shock produces a different response in different parts of the study region. The non-stationarity may emerge due to: (i) sampling variation – called nuisance variation or not real spatial non-stationarity, (ii) relationship intrinsically different across space – real spatial non-stationarity, and (iii) model misspecification. If non-stationary data is modelled with a stationary model, the consequence may be (i) wrong conclusions are drawn, and (ii) the residuals of the model might be highly autocorrelated.
In global models, spatial processes are assumed to be stationary and as such are location independent. The local models like spatial expansion method [Casetti 1972, 1997; Jones and Casetti 1992], and geographically weighted regression (GWR) model decompose the global model and produce results that are location dependent. These models are based on the first law of geography: “everything is related to everything else, but closer things are more related”. These models address the spatial/geographical non-stationarity directly as they allow the relationship to vary over space, i e, regression coefficients need not be the same everywhere over the space. The expansion model suggested by Casetti (1972, 1997) suffers from some limitations like: (i) the technique has been restricted to displaying trends in relationships over space with the complexity of measured trends being dependent upon the complexity of expansion equations, and, therefore, the spatially varying parameters obtained through the expansion method might obscure important local variations to the broad trends represented by the expansion equations; (ii) the form of expansion equations needs to be assumed a priori; (iii) the expansion equations must be deterministic to remove problems of estimation in the terminal model [Fotheringham, Brusdon and Charlton 2002]. All these problems are overcome by GWR. We, therefore, have used GWR in our analysis for detecting spatial heterogeneity and patterns in regression parameters.
In the regular OLS model, regression parameters at ith location
are estimated by: | |
---|---|
β = (X'X)–1 X'Y In GWR, they are given by [Lee 2004]: β = (X'WiX)–1 X'WiY | ...(13) ...(14) |
where X and Y are independent and dependent variables respectively, and Wi is an n-by-n local weight matrix, whose offdiagonal elements are zero and diagonal elements denote the
geographical weighting of observed data for point/region i. urbanised districts – Mumbai, Thane, Pune and Nagpur account
That is
0 ... 0 0wi2 ... 0 Wi =
wi1
[]
...(15)0 0 ...
win Where win denotes the weight of the data at point n on the calibration of the model around point i. These weights will vary over space with i, which distinguishes GWR from the traditional weighted least square, where the weighting matrix is constant. The study uses the Gaussian weighting method.
III Regional and Sectoral Distribution of Income and Its Growth
The regional shares of aggregate and sectoral income in Maharashtra, presented in Table 1 for the year 1993-94 and 200203 show the following: (1) Economic development in the state is highly polarised and metropolitised, as about two-fifths of the Net State Income comes from the Konkan region; also four highly for about one-half of the NSDP. (2) Not only the four major urbanised districts just mentioned also account for more than 55 per cent of the tertiary sector income, but the Konkan region alone accounts for about 46 per cent of this sector. (3) There has been a significant dispersal of industrial activities from the Konkan to other regions in the state. (4) Whereas shares of other regions in primary sector income have stagnated or declined, there has been a significant increase of the share of western Maharashtra in this sector. (5) Although there has been a marginal increase in the shares of the four highly urbanised districts in NSDP over the years, inter-district inequalities in sectoral as well as aggregate income have declined in 2002-03 in comparison to 1993-94.
The Konkan region has had a significantly high share of the state income over the years. The region accounts for about 25 per cent of the state population, but its share in state’s income has been more than 40 per cent. Table 2 shows that as against per capita state income of Rs 12,326 and Rs 15,484 in 199394 and 2002-03, the region had per capita income of Rs 20,424 and Rs 23,938, respectively, in the same years. Although, Konkan is a highly developed region of the state, spatially polarised
Table 1: Regional Share in Sectoral and Total NSDP (at 1993-94 Prices) and Population in Maharashtra
(Per cent)
Regions Population Primary Sector Secondary Sector Tertiary Sector Total 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03
Greater Mumbai 12.5 12.3 1.5 2.2 29.8 27.3 32.0 31.6 24.8 25.7 Thane 6.7 8.7 2.7 2.8 13.9 12.8 9.8 10.6 9.6 9.9 Raigad 2.3 2.3 2.0 1.7 8.4 4.2 1.6 1.7 3.8 2.4 Ratnagiri 1.9 1.7 2.7 1.7 1.0 1.3 1.1 1.2 1.4 1.3 Sindhudurg 1.0 0.9 3.3 1.2 0.4 0.5 0.7 0.7 1.1 0.7 I Konkan div/region 24.6 25.8 12.2 9.5 53.5 46.1 45.1 45.9 40.7 40.0 Nashik 4.9 5.1 6.2 7.4 4.8 5.4 3.3 3.6 4.4 4.7 Dhule 3.2 3.1 2.8 2.5 1.0 1.2 1.8 2.0 1.8 1.9 Jalgaon 4.0 3.8 4.8 5.7 1.9 1.8 2.5 2.8 2.8 3.0 Ahmadnagar 4.3 4.2 3.8 4.9 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.7 2.7 3.0 II Nashik division 16.4 16.2 17.6 20.5 9.8 10.7 10.3 11.1 11.7 12.5 Pune 7.0 7.5 5.4 7.5 11.5 13.8 8.1 8.3 8.6 9.6 Satara 3.1 2.9 3.6 4.5 1.5 2.0 1.9 2.1 2.2 2.5 Sangli 2.8 2.6 3.9 4.6 1.4 1.8 2.3 2.2 2.4 2.5 Kolhapur 4.1 3.6 5.1 6.0 2.8 3.4 3.3 3.3 3.5 3.8 Solapur 3.8 4.0 3.7 4.4 2.1 2.6 3.0 2.9 2.9 3.1 III Pune division 20.8 20.6 21.8 27.0 19.4 23.6 18.6 18.8 19.5 21.4 Western Maharashtra(II+III) 37.2 36.8 39.4 47.5 29.2 34.3 28.8 29.9 31.2 33.9 Aurangabad 2.8 3.1 2.5 2.1 3.2 3.2 2.0 1.9 2.5 2.3 Jalna 1.7 1.7 2.2 2.0 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.8 1.0 0.9 Parbhani 2.7 2.5 3.8 3.6 0.7 0.8 1.5 1.4 1.8 1.6 Beed 2.3 2.2 2.9 3.1 0.6 0.8 1.3 1.2 1.4 1.4 Nanded 3.0 3.0 2.8 2.7 1.0 1.1 1.8 1.6 1.8 1.7 Osmanabad 1.6 1.5 2.1 1.7 0.4 0.5 0.7 0.7 0.9 0.8 Latur 2.1 2.2 2.2 2.3 0.6 0.7 1.3 1.1 1.3 1.2 IV Aurangabad div/Marathwada (IV) 16.3 16.1 18.5 17.5 6.9 7.7 9.4 8.7 10.6 9.9 Buldhana 2.4 2.3 2.5 2.2 0.6 0.7 1.6 1.4 1.5 1.3 Akola 2.8 2.7 3.2 3.0 0.9 1.1 2.3 1.9 2.0 1.9 Amravati 2.8 2.7 4.5 3.4 0.9 1.0 2.0 2.0 2.2 2.0 Yavatmal 2.6 2.5 3.6 3.7 0.8 0.9 1.5 1.4 1.7 1.7 V Amravati division 10.6 10.2 13.8 12.4 3.1 3.7 7.3 6.6 7.4 6.8 Wardha 1.3 1.3 1.6 1.8 0.5 0.6 0.9 0.9 0.9 1.0 Nagpur 4.2 4.2 3.8 4.5 3.8 4.4 5.4 4.9 4.6 4.7 Bhandara 2.7 2.4 3.2 2.3 1.3 1.5 1.2 1.4 1.7 1.6 Chandrapur 2.2 2.1 4.2 3.7 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.3 2.0 1.8 Gadchiroli 1.0 1.0 3.3 0.8 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.4 1.0 0.4 VI Nagpur division 11.4 11.0 16.1 13.1 7.3 8.2 9.3 8.9 10.1 9.4 Vidarbha (V+VI) 22.0 21.2 29.9 25.5 10.4 11.9 16.6 15.6 17.5 16.2 Maharashtra 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Note: NSDP data for 2002-03 are provisional. Source: Computed data obtaned from Directorate of Economics and Statistics, Government of Maharashtra, Mumbai.
Economic and Political Weekly May 6, 2006 developments in the region are also glaring. Development has been concentrated in Greater Mumbai, Thane and Raigad, while Ratnagiri and Sindhudurg districts in the region have been as worse off as any backward districts of Vidharbha or Marathawada. As expected, the highest developed district in the region (and also in the state) has been Greater Mumbai, with per capita income of Rs 24,382 in 1993-94 and Rs 32,402 in 2002-03, while Ratnagiri, the least developed district in the region, has had per capita income of only Rs 8,888 and Rs 11,850, respectively, in the same years. Although Greater Mumbai has been the highest developed district in the state over the years, it should also be kept in mind that about a half of the population in the district/ metropolis lives in slums with scanty provisions of drinking water, sanitation, health, hygiene, housing, etc; literally five to six million people live next to latrines, on pavements, plinths, platforms, and have no access to anything called civic amenities [Desarda 1996].
After the Konkan region, western Maharashtra is the second most economically developed region in the state. However, the region has had a lower total per capita income than the state average over the years (Table 2). Western Maharashtra comprises two divisions, namely, Nashik and the Pune. As evident from Table 2, this region too has not escaped from polarised development. It is the Pune division in the region where most of the economic development is concentrated, while the situation in Nashik division is not very different from that in the Vidarbha or Marathwada region. In fact, Dhule and Ahmednagar districts in Nashik division ranked 30th (the last) and 22nd in terms of total per capita income among the 30 districts of the state in 1993-94. The ranking of these two districts has relatively improved in 2003-04, but they still occupy low ranks, that is 24th and 18th, respectively. The ranking of all the districts in terms of total per capita income in western Maharashtra has improved over the years. Pune, which was the 4th most developed district in the state in 1993-94, has become the 2nd most developed district in 2002-03. The other districts, which have experienced significant upward mobility in their ranks, are Satara, Sangli and Jalgaon.
Among the four major regions in the state, Vidarbha has been the 3rd most developed region, while the least developed region has been Marathwada. In fact, this pattern of development ranking has been consistent over years, and other studies which even have
Table 2: Sectoral Shares and Regional Per Capita Income (at 1993-94 Prices) in Maharashtra, 1993-94 and 2002-03
Region/District Sectoral Share in Total Regional/District Income Ranks of the Districts Based on Per Capita Income Total/Aggregate Per Capita (Per Cent) Income (Rs) Primary Sector Secondary Sector Tertiary Sector Primary Sector Secondary Sector Tertiary Sector 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 2002-03 1993-94 Rank 2002-03 Rank
1 Greater Mumbai 1.3 1.4 37.6 27.5 61.1 71.1 30 30 2 1 1 1 24,382 1 32,402 1 2 Thane 6.0 4.7 45.4 33.6 48.6 61.7 29 29 3 4 2 2 17,521 3 17,569 3 3 Raigad 11.1 11.6 69.0 45.7 19.9 42.7 27 27 1 3 11 8 20,245 2 16,009 6 4 Ratnagiri 41.0 21.3 22.8 25.2 36.3 53.6 7 20 10 9 26 14 8,888 15 11,850 15 5 Sindhudurg 61.5 26.7 69.0 16.6 28.2 56.7 2 11 18 16 14 7 13,480 6 13,010 10 I Konkan division/region 6.4 3.9 41.1 29.8 52.6 66.3 IV IV I I I I 20,424 I 23,938 I 6 Nashik 29.9 26.1 34.0 29.7 36.1 44.2 12 8 6 6 12 15 11,050 9 14,092 8 7 Dhule 34.0 21.9 16.8 16.4 49.2 61.7 26 26 22 21 22 17 6,796 30 9,344 24 8 Jalgaon 36.3 30.9 21.0 15.3 42.7 53.8 16 5 16 18 16 10 8,605 19 12,343 13 9 Ahmadnagar 29.6 27.0 25.6 20.8 44.8 52.2 25 14 11 15 21 18 7,868 22 10,920 18 II Nashik division 32.0 26.8 26.3 22.2 41.7 51.0 – – – – – – 8,787 – 11,918 – 10 Pune 13.4 12.8 42.0 37.2 44.5 50.0 28 21 4 2 4 4 15,058 4 19,685 2 11 Satara 35.5 30.1 22.3 20.9 42.2 49.0 17 4 13 10 17 11 8,632 17 13,416 9 12 Sangli 35.7 30.1 18.5 18.2 45.8 51.7 6 1 15 12 7 6 10,381 12 14,676 7 13 Kolhapur 30.8 26.1 24.8 23.2 44.5 50.6 8 3 8 8 5 5 11,567 8 16,210 5 14 Solapur 27.8 23.7 23.1 22.0 49.0 54.3 22 17 12 13 8 13 8,628 18 11,958 14 III Pune division 23.8 20.7 31.1 28.5 45.1 50.8 – – – – – – 11,573 – 16,079 –
Western Maharashtra
(II+III) 26.9 23.0 29.3 26.1 43.8 50.9 III I II II II II 10344 II 14243 II 15 Aurangabad 21.8 15.4 40.4 36.4 37.7 48.2 24 28 5 7 10 20 10,789 11 11,494 16 16 Jalna 46.9 35.0 12.9 16.4 40.3 48.6 11 13 28 24 27 29 7,077 28 8,691 27 17 Parbhani 46.1 37.2 12.9 13.6 41.0 49.2 5 9 25 26 23 26 8,110 20 9,732 23 18 Beed 43.3 36.3 13.7 14.7 43.0 49.0 13 10 26 23 25 25 7,526 24 9,780 22 19 Nanded 33.9 26.5 17.6 17.6 48.5 55.9 21 24 19 20 19 24 7,304 27 8,691 27 20 Osmanabad 49.0 34.1 13.2 15.3 37.8 50.7 10 15 27 27 29 28 7,063 29 8,463 29 21 Latur 36.9 31.3 15.1 14.6 47.9 54.1 20 19 24 28 20 27 7,376 26 8,561 28 IV Aurangabad division/
Marathwada region 37.3 29.1 20.5 20.2 42.2 50.7 II III IV IV IV IV 8,035 IV 9,498 IV 22 Buldhana 37.3 27.3 12.0 13.4 50.7 59.3 19 22 29 29 15 21 7,485 25 8,938 25 23 Akola 33.1 26.7 13.6 15.0 53.3 58.3 18 16 20 19 6 16 8,992 14 10,639 19 24 Amravati 44.2 28.7 12.6 13.4 43.2 57.9 4 12 21 22 9 12 9,610 13 11,337 17 25 Yavatmal 44.7 37.0 14.3 13.5 41.0 49.5 9 6 23 25 24 23 7,957 21 10,128 21 V Amravati division 39.9 29.9 13.2 13.9 47.0 56.3 – – – – – – 8,558 – 10,314 – 26 Wardha 36.4 29.8 17.7 16.4 45.8 53.7 15 7 17 17 13 9 8,642 16 12,359 12 27 Nagpur 17.6 15.9 26.3 24.3 56.1 59.9 23 18 7 5 3 3 13,504 5 17,346 4 28 Bhandara 40.8 23.7 24.5 25.0 34.7 51.3 14 23 14 14 28 22 7,858 23 10,194 20 29 Chandrapur 45.0 34.4 22.0 21.3 32.9 44.4 3 2 9 11 18 19 10,912 10 12,752 11 30 Gadchiroli 73.3 33.2 6.8 14.9 19.9 51.9 1 25 30 30 30 30 11,784 7 6,453 30 VI Nagpur division 33.8 22.9 22.6 22.6 43.6 54.6 – – – – – – 10,952 – 13,332 –
Vidarbha region (V+VI) 36.4 25.8 18.6 18.9 45.0 55.3 I II III III III III 9,801 III 11,876 III
Maharashtra 21.3 16.4 31.3 25.8 47.4 57.7 – – – – – 12,326 – 15,484 –
Note: Ranks in the Roman letter are ranks of the regions. Source: The same as in Table 1.
Economic and Political Weekly May 6, 2006 taken many other aspects into consideration while computing development ranks for the regions also show the same regional ranking/development pattern [Government of Maharashtra 2002, 1984; Prabhu and Sarker 2003, 1992; Shaban and Bhole 1997]. The per capita income in Vidarbha and Marathwada was Rs 9,801 and Rs 8,035 in 1993-94, and Rs 11,876 and Rs 9,498, respectively, in 2002-03. As expected, except Nagpur, which ranked 5th and 4th respectively in the two reference years, the ranks of other districts have been very low. The ranks of four districts (Gadchiroli, Chandrapur, Amravati and Akola), out of the total nine districts in Vidarbha, and three districts (Aurangabad, Parbhani and Latur) in Marathwada out of the total seven districts in the region, have experienced decline in their ranks. Gadchiroli in Vidarbha, which was the 7th most developed district in the state in 1993-94, has become the least developed district in 2003
04. In fact, the district has experienced a decline in per capita income from Rs 11,784 in 1993-94 to Rs 6,453 in 2002-03. Besides Gadchiroli, the only other district, which experienced a decline in per capita income in the state, is Raigad. In Raigad, the per capita income has declined from Rs 20,245 to Rs 16,009 during the above mentioned period. In case of Gadchiroli, the decline of income is due to decline of the primary sector, while in case of Raigad it is due to the flight of (registered) industries. The contribution of registered manufacturing in Net District Domestic Product of Raigad was Rs 2,331 crore in 1993-94, which declined to Rs 1,151 crore in 2002-03. Due to development of Navi Mumbai, and the imposition of various punitive taxes and restrictions, such as high property taxes, high water charges and implementation of environmental regulation, etc, this has resulted in the flight of many industries from the vicinity of Mumbai and Navi Mumbai. Among other things, the increased cost of labour and land has also contributed to this industrial flight and closures.
Maharashtra has had a highly metropolitised economy. The four highly urbanised districts, Greater Mumbai, Thane, Pune and Nagpur accounted for about 48 per cent of NSDP in 199394 and 50 per cent in 2002-03. Thus, this metropolitisation of the state economy has increased over the years. The share of Greater Mumbai in the NSDP has increased from 24.8 per cent in 1993-94 to 25.7 per cent in 2002-03. The shares of Thane, Pune and Nagpur have marginally increased from 9.6 per cent,
8.6 per cent and 4.6 per cent to 9.9 per cent, 9.6 per cent and
4.7 per cent, respectively, during the reference period. In comparison to their shares in the state income, these four districts together accounted for only 30.4 per cent and 32.7 per cent of the total population in the state in 1993-94 and 2002-03, respectively. As expected, economic liberalisation has further contributed in accentuating polarised and metropolitised development in the state, and this needs to be overcome.
The share of the tertiary sector in the state income has significantly increased over the years. It constituted only 47.4 per cent of the NSDP in 1993-94 but has increased to 57.7 per cent in 2002-03 (Table 2); correspondingly the shares of primary and secondary sectors have declined from 21.3 per cent to 16.4 per cent and 31.3 per cent to 25.8 per cent, respectively, during the period. Thus, the share of primary sector in the state economy, on which about two-thirds of the state’s population depends for its livelihood, has got marginalised over the years. Table 1 shows that about 46 per cent of the tertiary sector income in the state comes from the Konkan region, and Greater Mumbai alone accounts for about 32 per cent of this sector. The four highly urbanised districts, with metropolitan cities, Greater Mumbai, Thane, Pune and Nagpur together have accounted for more than 55 per cent of the tertiary sector income in the state over the yeaRs The share of Greater Mumbai, Thane, Pune and Nagpur in the tertiary sector income was 32.0 per cent, 9.8 per cent, 8.1 per cent and 5.4 per cent, respectively, in 1993-94 and 31.6 per cent, 10.6 per cent, 8.3 per cent and 4.9 per cent, respectively, in 2002-03. Among the metropolitan centres, the worst position is that of Nagpur. Its location in an economically backward area/ region and far off from Mumbai has led to the stagnation of its share in the state economy. In fact, the declining share of tertiary sector income and the stagnating share of its population tell a lot about this. Although, dispersal of secondary sector activities from Greater Mumbai, Thane and Raigad has led to a marginal increase in Nagpur’s share in the state’s secondary sector income, this gain of the district is not unique as many other districts, albeit backward, have also benefited from this dispersal/flight of
Table 3: Annual Growth Rate of Per Capita Income (at 1993-94Prices) in Maharashtra, 1993-94 to 2002-03
(Per cent)
Region/District Primary Sector Secondary Tertiary Sector Total/ Sector Aggregate Growth Rank Growth Rank Growth Rank Growth Rank Rate Rate Rate Rate
1 Greater Mumbai 4.35 1 -0.32 27 4.96 15.5 3.21 10 2 Thane -2.72 24 -3.26 29 2.72 30 0.03 27 3 Raigad -2.10 23 -6.92 30 6.03 7 -2.57 29 4 Ratnagiri -4.01 28 4.39 3 7.82 1 3.24 9 5 Sindhudurg -9.21 29 4.95 2 7.65 2 -0.40 28 I Konkan division/
region -3.53 IV -1.78 IV 4.43 III 1.78 IV 6 Nashik 1.08 11 1.11 25 4.96 15.5 2.63 16 7 Dhule -1.33 20 3.28 8 6.24 6 3.60 8 8 Jalgaon 2.25 5 0.53 26 6.78 4 4.09 2 9 Ahmadnagar 2.65 3 1.34 22.5 5.49 9 3.71 6 II Nashik division 1.44 – 1.50 – 5.78 – 3.44 – 10 Pune 2.45 4 1.64 21 4.35 21 3.02 11 11 Satara 3.11 2 4.29 4 6.76 5 5.02 1 12 Sangli 1.97 6 3.77 6 5.33 11 3.93 4 13 Kolhapur 1.96 7 3.09 13 5.32 12 3.82 5 14 Solapur 1.86 8 3.14 12 4.87 18 3.69 7 III Pune division 2.13 – 2.72 – 5.11 – 3.72 –
Western Maharashtra
(II+III) 1.83 I 2.32 II 5.35 I 3.62 I 15 Aurangabad -3.11 27 -0.48 28 3.48 27 0.70 26 16 Jalna -0.96 18 5.10 1 4.47 19 2.31 17 17 Parbhani -0.35 15 2.63 15 4.14 22 2.05 18 18 Beed 0.96 12 3.78 5 4.45 20 2.95 12 19 Nanded -0.81 17 1.98 19 3.57 25.5 1.95 21 20 Osmanabad -2.02 22 3.68 7 5.41 10 2.03 19 21 Latur -0.19 14 1.28 24 3.05 28 1.67 25 IV Aurangabad
division/Marathwada
region -0.89 II 1.70 III 3.97 IV 1.88 III 22 Buldhana -1.49 21 3.23 9 3.79 24 2.00 20 23 Akola -0.53 16 2.94 14 2.92 29 1.88 22 24 Amravati -2.93 25 2.55 16 5.23 13 1.85 23 25 Yavatmal 0.58 13 2.04 17 4.90 17 2.72 15 V Amravati division -1.12 – 2.67 – 4.17 – 2.10 – 26 Wardha 1.77 9 3.16 11 5.92 8 4.06 3 27 Nagpur 1.63 10 1.89 20 3.57 25.5 2.82 14 28 Bhandara -3.10 26 3.18 10 7.50 3 2.93 13 29 Chandrapur -1.27 19 1.34 22.5 5.19 14 1.75 24 30 Gadchiroli -14.34 30 2.01 18 4.04 23 -6.47 30 VI Nagpur division -2.15 – 2.22 – 4.78 – 2.21 –
Vidarbha region
(V+VI) -1.65 III 2.36 I 4.53 II 2.18 II
Maharashtra -0.34 – 0.41 – 4.83 – 2.57 –
Note: Roman numerals show ranks of the regions. Source: The same as in Table 1.
industries. The least developed district in terms of tertiary sector per capita income has again been Gadchiroli. As expected, regional order in development of the tertiary sector has been that of Konkan, followed by western Maharashtra, Vidarbha and Marathwada, and this order has remained unchained over the study period.
In contrast to the tertiary sector, the share of the four highly urbanised districts in the state in the secondary sector has experienced a marginal decline. Their collective share of 59.0 per cent in 1993-94 has declined to 58.3 per cent in 2002-03. However, regional ranking in secondary sector per capita income is the same as that of the tertiary sector and total per capita income.
Increasing marginalisation of the primary sector, of which a major component is agriculture, is a matter of concern. About two-thirds of the state population depends on this sector, yet the sector account for about one-sixth of the NSDP. Not only the share of the primary sector has declined over the years at the state level but also in all the regions (Table 2). It is not only the diminishing share of the primary sector that is a cause of concern, but in absolute terms as well, the per capita income originating from this sector has declined at the state level and in all the regions, except in western Maharashtra. Per capita income originating from this sector was Rs 2,624 in 1993-94 at the state level, which declined to Rs 2,544 in 2002-03. In Konkan, Marathwada and Vidarbha, it has declined from Rs 1,299, Rs 2,994 and Rs 3,564 to Rs 940, Rs 2,762 and Rs 3,063, respectively, during the same period. Western Maharashtra and all its districts (except Dhule) have experienced an increase in primary sector per capita income. In the region, per capita income from this sector has increased from Rs 2,782 to Rs 3,274 during the abovementioned period, albeit the share of the sector in the regional total income has declined from 26.9 per cent to 23.0 per cent. The major reason behind this success of western Maharashtra is development of irrigation in this region, and this has led to high agricultural development. Vidarbha ranked first in terms of per capita income from the primary sector in 1993-94, followed by Marathwada, western Maharashtra and Konkan, but in 200203 western Maharashtra has taken over the first rank and is followed by Vidarbha, Marathwada and Konkan. The overall decline of this sector in Gadchiroli and agricultural decline in Sindhudurg has led to the drastic fall in the ranks of these districts in terms of per capita income from this sector. The rank of these two districts has gone down from 1st and 2nd in 1993-94 to 25th and 11th, respectively, in 2002-03.
Table 3 presents the annual compound growth rates (per cent) of per capita real income for the state and its regions, divisions and districts. At the aggregate level, the per capita income in the state during the period 1993-94 – 2002-03 has grown by 2.57 per cent per annum. In the state, western Maharashtra has been the only region, which has experienced a growth rate above the state average (3.62 per cent per annum). It is also noteworthy that in none of the districts in western Maharashtra, the growth rate has been lower than the state average. In terms of the growth rate of total per capita income, western Maharashtra ranks 1st
(3.62 per cent per annum) and is followed by Vidarbha (2.18 per cent), Marathwada (1.88 per cent) and the Konkan (1.78 per cent). Three districts, namely, Gadchiroli, Raigad and Sindhudurg have experienced negative growth in their total per capita income because of the above-mentioned reasons. The negative growth rate in these districts during the period has been –6.47 per cent, -2.57 per cent and –0.40 per cent per annum, respectively.
In comparison to the growth rate of 0.41 per cent per annum of the secondary sector per capita income, the tertiary sector per capita income in the state has experienced a growth rate of 4.83 per cent per annum. In the tertiary sector as well, western Maharashtra has maintained its lead and is followed by Vidarbha, Konkan and Marathwada (Table 3). None of the districts in the state has experienced a negative growth rate of per capita income from this sector. Konkan has experienced industrial decline over the years and per capita income from this sector in the region has declined by –1.78 per cent per annum. All the three major districts in the region, the Greater Mumbai (annual growth rate -0.32 per cent), Thane (-3.26 per cent) and Raigad (-6.92 per cent) have experienced a negative growth rates. Outside Konkan, the only other district experiencing a negative growth rate in per capita income from this sector has been Aurangabad (-0.48 per cent). In the growth rate of secondary sector per capita income,
Table 4: Regional Inequality in Per Capita Income (at 1993-94Prices) in Maharashtra
Period Theil’s Inequality Gini CV Moran’s I Global Intra-Inter-(Per Cent) Value Proba-Regional Regional bility (z)
A Aggregate/Total Per Capita Income 1993-94 0.065 0.026 0.039 0.190 3.491 0.472 0.000 1994-95 0.069 0.025 0.044 0.200 3.672 0.487 0.000 1995-96 0.075 0.028 0.047 0.209 3.805 0.506 0.000 1996-97 0.061 0.029 0.032 0.189 3.436 0.429 0.000 1997-98 0.082 0.030 0.052 0.217 3.936 0.530 0.000 1998-99 0.071 0.030 0.041 0.201 3.598 0.484 0.000 1999-00 0.059 0.030 0.029 0.180 3.294 0.451 0.000 2000-01 0.063 0.031 0.032 0.189 3.495 0.443 0.000 2001-02 0.057 0.029 0.028 0.177 3.246 0.414 0.000 2002-03 0.060 0.031 0.029 0.180 3.324 0.408 0.000 B Primary Sector Per Capita Income 1993-94 0.111 0.098 0.013 0.233 7.085 0.329 0.001 1994-95 0.132 0.120 0.013 0.252 7.274 0.289 0.003 1995-96 0.123 0.105 0.019 0.252 6.908 0.326 0.001 1996-97 0.096 0.085 0.011 0.231 6.381 0.303 0.002 1997-98 0.135 0.107 0.028 0.273 6.827 0.365 0.000 1998-99 0.094 0.084 0.010 0.226 6.199 0.359 0.000 1999-00 0.060 0.041 0.019 0.178 5.792 0.379 0.000 2000-01 0.080 0.062 0.018 0.215 6.321 0.288 0.003 2001-02 0.062 0.043 0.019 0.183 5.775 0.289 0.003 2002-03 0.062 0.043 0.019 0.181 5.967 0.336 0.001 C Secondary Sector Per Capita Income 1993-94 0.378 0.180 0.198 0.452 9.676 0.536 0.000 1994-95 0.351 0.182 0.169 0.441 9.600 0.529 0.000 1995-96 0.366 0.185 0.181 0.455 9.910 0.526 0.000 1996-97 0.299 0.157 0.142 0.416 8.981 0.502 0.000 1997-98 0.321 0.159 0.162 0.427 9.085 0.524 0.000 1998-99 0.316 0.156 0.160 0.424 8.938 0.524 0.000 1999-00 0.231 0.116 0.115 0.372 8.089 0.556 0.000 2000-01 0.230 0.114 0.115 0.367 7.976 0.540 0.000 2001-02 0.216 0.108 0.108 0.357 7.719 0.535 0.000 2002-03 0.202 0.097 0.104 0.348 7.598 0.538 0.000 D Tertiary Sector Per Capita Income 1993-94 0.104 0.069 0.035 0.217 4.440 0.260 0.006 1994-95 0.106 0.070 0.036 0.220 4.480 0.273 0.004 1995-96 0.105 0.062 0.043 0.221 4.438 0.299 0.002 1996-97 0.105 0.069 0.036 0.219 4.405 0.286 0.003 1997-98 0.105 0.068 0.037 0.217 4.326 0.288 0.003 1998-99 0.105 0.067 0.038 0.220 4.342 0.311 0.002 1999-00 0.094 0.053 0.041 0.206 4.090 0.360 0.000 2000-01 0.093 0.052 0.040 0.205 4.076 0.354 0.000 2001-02 0.092 0.052 0.040 0.205 4.035 0.351 0.001 2002-03 0.093 0.052 0.042 0.207 4.040 0.355 0.000
Notes: 1 Coefficient of variation (CV), and Moran’s I have been computed using log of per capita income. 2 Division level data are used for computing Theil’s inter-regional inequality. Source: As in Table 1.
Vidarbha (2.36 per cent), western Maharashtra (2.32 per cent) and Marathwada (1.70 per cent) have occupied first, second and third ranks, respectively.
Primary sector per capita income in the state during 1993-94
– 2003-04 has declined at the rate of –0.34 per cent per annum, and except western Maharashtra, all the regions have experienced a negative growth rate. The negative growth rates in Konkan, Marathwada and Vidarbha have been of the order of –3.53 per cent, -0.89 per cent and -1.65 per cent per annum, respectively. Out of the 30 districts in the state, 17 districts have experienced a negative growth rate in the primary sector per capita income, the highest being in Gadchiroli (-14.34 per cent), followed by Sindhudurg (-9.21 per cent), Ratnagiri (-4.01 per cent) and Aurangabad (-3.11 per cent). In contrast to the negative growth rate in other regions, the per capita income from this sector in western Maharashtra has experienced an annual growth rate of
1.83 per cent (2.13 per cent in Pune division and 1.44 per cent in Nashik division). The negative growth rate of primary sector income in the most of the backward districts does not auger well for regionally balanced and socio-politically sustainable development in the state. As mining, forestry, as well as fishery resources are depleting fast, on which these backward districts were dependent, there is a need to put a high emphasis on agricultural development in these districts. In this regard, the western Maharashtra model of agricultural development (spurred by irrigation development) can be an effective model for economic development of these districts. Development of the agricultural sector would lead to increase in income, which would ensure education and skill formation among the general masses. The rise in income and skill level can lead to attraction of industries in these areas and development of other non-farm sectors. In this way all the sectors of the economy can cumulatively and synergetically evolve, leading to over all high economic and social development in the districts/regions.
IV Spatial Association and Inequality
Moran scatter plots for the total as well as the sectoral per capita incomes of the districts in the state are given in Figures 1A through 1H. The figures show a strong positive spatial association in economic development in the state. In fact, global Moran’s I for all the sectors establishes this fact (Table 4). The strong spatial association shows that the relatively highly developed districts are lying in a geographically contiguous area or beside one another. This indicates strong regional inequality in economic development in the state. Table 5 presents the frequency distribution of locations of districts in different quadrants of the Moran scatter plots of all the districts for all the three sectors as well as total per capita income together. The high frequency of location of the districts of Marathwada and Vidarbha in quadrant III indicates a contiguous geographical area of underdevelopment and deprivation. And, high frequency of location of districts of Konkan and western Maharashtra in quadrant I shows relatively high development in the regions. The location of Greater Mumbai, Thane, and Raigad in quadrant III is because of low development of the primary sector and due to that they have a frequency of 10 each, equal to the number years of data used in the analysis.
Along with Global Moran’s I, Table 4 also provides the Gini coefficient, CV and Theil’s global as well as decomposed inequality indices. All the inequality indices show that there has been only a very marginal decline in district level inequality in total as well as tertiary sector per capita income in the state. However, the decline of inequality in the primary and secondary sector per capita income has been more significant. What is obvious from the indices given in Table 4 is that there has not been a smooth decline in the inequality in per capita income but it has fluctuated over the years in case of the aggregate as well as the sectoral incomes.
Decomposed Theil’s inequality index shows that till 1998-99, interregional inequality (read as inter-divisional inequality, as division-wise data is used for this) accounted for the major proportion of the “global” inequality. However, after that the contributions of inter-regional and intra-regional inequality in the “global” inequality have become almost equal. Intra-regional inequalities are the main cause of inequality in primary sector income. While in the secondary sector, intra-regional and interregional inequalities contribute almost equally to global inequality. Global inequality in tertiary sector income has been high due to intra-regional inequality, but over the years the gap between both the inequalities has narrowed down due to a decline in intraregional inequality and increase in inter-regional inequality. However, intra-regional inequality still remains high. It is
Table 5:Location of Districts in Different Quadrants Based
on Moran Scatter Plot of Per Capita Income of All the
Three Sectors and Total Per Capita Income Together
Districts Quadrant I Quadrant II Quadrant III Quadrant IV
Greater Mumbai 30 0 10 0 Thane 30 010 0 Raigad 29 1 10 0 Ratnagiri 13 27 0 0 Sindhudurg 23 15 1 1 Nashik 17 10 0 13 Dhule 032 8 0 Jalgaon 0 0 24 16 Ahmadnagar 7 24 6 3 Pune 30082 Satara 19 18 0 3 Sangli 35 1 1 3 Kolhapur 29 0 0 11 Solapur 14 15 5 6 Aurangabad 0 9 12 19 Jalna 6 034 0 Parbhani 5 0 31 4 Beed 6031 3 Nanded 0 931 0 Osmanabad 6 0 31 3 Latur 4 531 0 Buldhana 0 9 31 0 Akola 3 625 6 Amravati 16 0 19 5 Yavatmal 6 4 30 0 Wardha 19 11 9 1 Nagpur 4 7 029 Bhandara 8 13 15 4 Chandrapur 11 0 10 19 Gadchiroli 7 13 16 4
Note and Source:As in Table 1.
Table 6:
σσσσσ
Parametres Primary Sector Secondary Sector Tertiary Sector Total
α 7.316(0.000) 10.237(0.000) | 4.586(0.000) 3.758(0.000) |
β -0.158(0.001) -0.269(0.000) R 2 0.740 0.899 | -0.057(0.000) -0.041(0.098) 0.871 0.217 |
Notes: p-values are in parentheses. | |
Source: The same as in Table 1. |

Figure 1: Moran Scatter Plots of Total and Sectoral Per Capita Income of Districts in Maharashtra
A Per Capita Total Income, 1993-94 B Per Capita Total Income, 2002-03
Spatial Lag of Standardised log
Spatial Lag of StandardisedSpatial Lag of StandardisedSpatial Lag of Standardised
Per Capita Income
log Per Capita Income log Per Capita Income log Per Capita Income

Spatial Lag of Standardised
Spatial Lag of StandardisedSpatial Lag of StandardisedSpatial Lag of Standardised
Log Per Capita Income
log Per Capita Income log Per Capita Income log Per Capita Income

Standardised log Per Capita Income Standardised log Per Capita Income C Primary Sector Per Capita Income, 1993-94 D Primary Sector Per Capita Income, 2002-03


Standardised log Per Capita Income Standardised log Per Capita Income E Secondary Sector Per Capita Income, 1993-94 F Secondary Sector Per Capital Income, 2002-03

.0
Standardised log Per Capita Income
Standardised log Per Capita Income
H Tertiary Sector Per Capita Income, 2002-03
G Tertiary Sector Per Capita Income, 1993-94


Standardised log Per Capita Income
Standardised log Per Capita Income
Note and Source:As in Table 1.
interesting to note that inter-regional inequality in the primary and tertiary sector has risen over the years, while its counterpart, intra-regional inequality has declined. This indicates that greater divisional homogeneity in development of these two sectors is emerging in the state. Increase in Global Moran’s I points out increased spatial association in tertiary sector and secondary sector income. However, at the aggregate level, spatial association has steadily weakened since 1997-98, indicating weakening of the nearest-neighbour bond in similarity of development in recent years.
V Regional Convergence and Spatial Spillover of Income
Regression of cross-sectional regional inequality in per capita income (coefficient of variation of log of per capita income in our case) on time is called σ-convergence analysis. If the estimated regression coefficient is negative, the regions are said to be converging and viceversa. The σ-convergence results presented in Table 6 show that at sectoral level, the convergence coefficientsthough not very high, are statistically significant at 1 per cent level of significance. However, the convergence coefficient for total/aggregate per capita income is significant only at about 10 per cent level. The speed of convergence of districts is highest in case of the secondary sector, followed by the primary and tertiary sectors.
With the help of the OLS method and other spatial econometric methods, an attempt has been made to measure β-convergence of sectoral and aggregate per capita income of the districts in the state. After statistical check and evaluation, the best results are reported in Table 7. Robust LM-lag test suggests that the OLS model for aggregate per capita income suffers from spatial lag autocorrelation. Therefore, inclusion of spatial lag value in the model has been done to overcome this problem. The Akaike information criterion and R2 also indicate that the spatial lag model is the relatively best model for aggregate per capita income data. The rate of β-convergence of districts income has been statistically significant indicating that homogeneity in economic development in the district is emerging. The implied annual rate of β-convergence of aggregate income is 2.6 per cent. This means that, on an average, it will take about 27 years to close one-half of the gaps between any district’s initial level of per capita income and common long-term per capita income of all the districts.
The β-convergence for all the sectoral incomes is also statistically significant. While the best regression models for primary and secondary sector incomes is OLS, it is the spatial error model, which gives the best result for tertiary sector income. The highest implied annual rate of β-convergence is found for the primary sector income (convergence rate 4.6 per cent), followed by the secondary (2.8 per cent) and tertiary sector (1.7 per cent) incomes. This means that these sectors would take about 15 years, 25 years and 41 years, respectively for half of the distance between the initial level of income and the sector specific steady-state levels to vanish [Fischer and Stirbock 2004].
This finding of the convergence (σ and β) of district income in Maharashtra is noteworthy in the context that state level per capita income in India shows divergence rather than convergence. The estimated coefficients for σ-convergence and β-convergenc2 for the period 1993-2003, for 29 states (except Mizoram) including Chandigarh union territory, are found to be 0.0662 (p-value= 0.000; R2 =0.877), and 0.127 (p-value= 0.050; R2 =0.126), respectively. The other studies, which have taken even longer periods into account also show the similar results [Dasgupta et al 2000; Ghosh et al 1998; Marjit and Mitra 1996; Raman 1996; Shaban 2002]. This shows that regional economies evolve in multiple ways. They can converge and diverge simultaneously at different regional scales. Due to this reason, the regional scale at which a study is undertaken becomes extremely important as it influences the results and conclusions.
It is possible that within Maharashtra some geographically contiguous group of districts may converge at a higher rate than the other groups, or there may be group of districts that may be diverging instead of converging, thus forming convergence/ divergence clubs. The global regression coefficients reported in Table 7 are not able to capture this. Therefore, a geographically weighted regression method, which provides convergence coefficient for all the districts, is used for this purpose.
Figures 2A through 2D show choropleth maps of local regression/convergence coefficient of districts of total as well as sectoral per capita income. The regression coefficients have been classified using Jenk’s method of classification/clustering. This method identifies breakpoints between classes using a statistical formula (Jenk’s optimisation). It minimises the sum of the variance within each of the classes and finds groupings and patterns inherent in data. This method of classification is highly efficient and reveals regional structures. The maps show that though all the districts in the state have experienced convergence (as they have negative regression coefficients), there are marked “convergence clubs” of districts in the aggregate as well as in sectoral per capita income. In total per capita income, districts of eastern and central Vidarbha show a high β-convergence rate, while districts of western Vidarbha, northern Konkan, along with Pune, Osmanabad and Solapur have a relatively low level of convergence. A geographically contiguous area comprising of north-western Maharashtra (Nashik division) and Akola and Beed districts shows a very low level of convergence.
In the primary sector, the per capita income for eastern and central Vidarbha again show a relatively higher rate of convergence. Southern Maharashtra (south-western Maharashtra and south Marathwada) shows moderate level of convergence, while the least level of convergence is found for the districts of Nashik division. β-convergence in secondary sector per capita income is higher in the districts of Konkan and south-western Maharashtra. Central Maharashtra has a moderately high rate of convergence, while the least rate of convergence is found in eastern Vidarbha, and southern Marathwada.
In case of the tertiary sector, the per capita incomes in the districts of Vidarbha, particularly northern Vidarbha is converging at a higher rate than the rest of the districts in the state. Konkan
Table 7: Estimates of
βββββ
Parametres Primary Secondary Tertiary Total Per Capita Sector Sector Sector Income OLS OLS Spatial OLS Spatial Error(ML) Lag(ML)
α 2.635 1.853 1.614 2.197 2.363
(0.011) ρ – – – – -0.198
(0.455) τ ––––– R2 0.308 0.562 0.253 0.125 0.148 AIC 14.454 -27.567 -46.851 -11.998 -10.541 Moran’s I 0.091 0.063 – -0.025 –
(0.227) (0.299) (0.812) LM-Lag Test 0.232 0.293 – 0.484 –
(0.629) (0.588) (0.486) Robust LM-Lag Test 0327 2.389 – 4.493 –
(0.566) (0.122) (0.034) LM-Error Test 0.514 2.347 – 0.039 –
(0.473) (0.126) (0.842) Robust LM-Error Test 0.608 2.640 – 4.048
(0.435) (0.267) (0.054) Implied convergence rate (θ) 0.046 0.028 0.017 0.025 0.026
Time taken (in years) to complete ½ distance to the steady-state 15.07 24.76 40.77 27.73 26.66
Notes: p-values are in parentheses. The implied convergence rate θ is calculated as θ = ln(β+1)/-t, where t is the length of time. AIC = Akaike Information Criterion; LM = Lagrange Multiplier Test; the ½ distance to the steady state is computed using formula ln(2)/θ.
Source: As in Table 1.
Figure 2: Spatial Differences in Beta Convergence of Total and Sectoral Per Capita Income in Maharashtra, 1993-94 to 2002-03
A Total Income B Primary Sector
0 | 70 | 140 | 280 kilometres | Beta Coefficient –0.22270 – –0.21980 –0.21979 – –0.21650 –0.21649 – –0.21110 –0.21109 – –0.20860 –0.20859 – –0.20540 |
---|---|---|---|---|
C Secondary Sector | ||||
0 | 70 | 140 | 280 kilometres | Beta Coefficient –0.35130 – –0.30370 –0.30369 – –0.23520 –0.23519 – –0.16650 –0.16649 – –0.09360 –0.09359 – –0.02290 |
Beta Coefficient –0.52690 – –0.43320 –0.43319 – –0.32740 –0.32739 – –0.25920 –0.25919 – –0.21070 –0.21069 – –0.16840
0 70 140 280 kilometres
D Tertiary Sector
Beta Coefficient –0.13270 – –0.12540 –0.12539 – –0.11020 –0.11019 – –0.09300 –0.09299 – –0.07640 –0.07639 – –0.04950
0 80 160 320 kilometres
Note:The classification of beta-coefficients (regression coefficients) for all the above figures is based on Jenk’s method.
along with Kolhapur seems to be evolving together at a moderate β-convergence rate, while the least rate of convergence is in Marathwada. The GWR results show that there is no spatial stability in regression coefficients but marked presence of heterogeneity in convergence, which was well masked by global β-convergence coefficients.
The presence of significant spatial error dependence in tertiary sector per capita income implies that the random shocks to a specific district would be propagated throughout the state. This is illustrated in Figures 3A through 3D, where we introduce shocks (equal to two times the standard error of the estimated spatial error specification) to the error terms for the four districts, viz, Greater Mumbai, Pune, Nagpur and Parbhani, and substituted the maximum likelihood estimates of the spatial error model coefficient into equation (12) to estimate the degree of spillover.
The selection of Greater Mumbai, Pune and Nagpur for the simulation is based on their regional demographic and economic prominence, while Parbhani was selected due to its interior location amidst underdeveloped districts. As expected, the shocks equal to two times of the standard error have highest impact on the districts they are applied to. Due to the shocks, the growth rates of tertiary sector per capita income over the period 199394 – 2002-03 in Greater Mumbai, Pune, Thane and Parbhani become about 15 per cent, 11 per cent, 12 per cent and 9 per cent higher than the estimates without the shocks to these districts.
There are clear spatial patterns of propagation of these shocks to other districts. The immediate neighbours of the districts, which are given shocks, experience a higher change in the growth rate, while the magnitude of shock/spillover dampens as distance from the focus increases. The simulation shows that shock (investment) in the district of Parbhani would be more beneficial for balanced regional development, as spillover due to the shock to the districts are propagated mostly to the underdeveloped districts.
VI Summary and Conclusions
The present paper analyses the growth and distribution of sectoral and aggregate incomes in the 10-year period 1993-94 to 2002-03 in various regions of Maharashtra. It is found that notwithstanding its overall high economic development, Maharashtra suffers from acute regional inequality. About a half of the total income in the state is accounted for only by the Konkan region, comprising the districts of Greater Mumbai, Thane, Raigad, Sindhudurg, and Ratnagiri. After the Konkan, western Maharashtra is the next highest developed region and is followed by Vidarbha and Marathwada. Four highly urbanised districts of Greater Mumbai, Thane, Pune and Nagpur also account for about onehalf of the total state income, and about 60 per cent of tertiary

Figure 3: Changes in Annual Growth Rate of Tertiary Sector Per Capita Income Due to Shock to Some Districts in Maharashtra,1993-94 to 2002-03
(Per cent)
B Shock to Pune
A Shock to Greater Mumbai
sector income. This shows that the state economy has become highly metropolitised.
The composition of the state income has changed much more in favour of the tertiary sector, which presently accounts for about 60 per cent of the NSDP, while the primary sector has got further marginalised, accounting for less than 13 per cent of the total income in the state in recent years. Significantly, about twothirds of the state’s population directly depends upon the primary sector for its livelihood. Therefore, the marginalisation of the primary sector is the marginalisation of two-thirds of the population of the state. Not only the share of the primary sector has gone down in different regions over the years but in absolute terms as well it has declined. Stagnation in forestry, mining and fishing has mainly led to the decline in primary sector per capita income. It was expected that the development of agriculture would compensate the losses (depletion of forest, mineral and fishing resources), however, it has not been so except in the western Maharashtra. One major spatial transformation that the state economy has experienced is in the secondary sector: the industries, which were concentrated in the Mumbai-Thane belt, have moved to other regions of the state (as well as out of the state).
There has been marked stability in the ranking of regions in economic development over the years in almost all the sectors. The Konkan region has been the highest developed region, followed by the western Maharashtra, Vidarbha and Marathwada.
The growth of regional economies in the state is mainly led by the tertiary sector. The share of the secondary sector is stagnating, while that of the primary sector has been declining. In comparison to 1993-94, the inequality in per capita district income (aggregate as well as sectoral) has declined in 2002-03. However, inequality in the secondary sector per capita income is higher than other sectors and the aggregate income, albeit the inequality in this sector has declined higher than the other sectors.
Conventional econometric (regression) methods have often been used to find outβ-convergence of regional incomes. However,the conventional econometric methods used for spatial data often yield imprecise or wrong results as spatial data are seldom stationary. To overcome this problem, the present study has used spatial econometric techniques to estimate coefficients for ßconvergence wherever needed.
District-wise sectoral and total per capita incomes in the state show σ and β-convergence. The local regression coefficients show marked presence of “convergence clubs”. The convergence is relatively higher in districts of Vidarbha in the primary, tertiary and aggregate per capita income, while in case of the secondary sector income, it is higher in the Konkan and western Maharashtra regions. District level sectoral as well as aggregate per capita income data show marked spatial association and so the spatial spillover and contagion effects. However, this contagion effect is higher in central Maharashtra than others, meaning thereby that shocks given in some regions are able to significantly affect larger number of districts. Shock to Parbhani due to its central location significantly affects larger number of districts than the shocks to other districts. This differential spatial spillover process of the same level of shocks at various locations in the state has implications for planning and development. The findings show that giving a boost to economies of interior and backward districts like Parbhani, instead of Greater Mumbai, Pune or Nagpur, would be more beneficial for balanced regional development of the state, as beneficial effects generated due to the shocks are propagated mainly to backward districts. The study shows that it is likely that most of the benefits due to investment and development in Greater Mumbai and Pune would remain concentrated in the Konkan and western Maharashtra region, already relatively highly developed regions in the state.
The convergence (σ and β) of regional economies within Maharashtra is also noteworthy in the context that state economies in India show divergence of per capita income rather than convergence. This shows that regional economies evolve in multiple ways. At one regional scale, they may be converging (or maintaining the same level of inequality), but at other regional scales, they may diverge. Due to this reason, the regional scale at which a study is undertaken becomes extremely important.

Email: shaban@tiss.edu
Notes
[The author is thankful to R N Sharma and an anonymous reviewer for helpful comments on the paper.]
1 In the spatial cross-regressive model, the spatial effect is dealt with the
introduction of a spatial lag of the explanatory variables, wX [Rey and
Montouri 1999], and, thus, the regression model becomes:
y = α + βX + τwy + ε
This specification implies that per capita income in a region is affected
not only by the independent variables, but also the spatial lag of the
independent variables. As the spatially lagged explanatory variable is
exogenous, the estimation of the spatial cross-regressive model can be
based on OLS [Rey and Montouri 1999]. 2 OLS estimator is used as no spatial dependence/association in the state
level per capita income is found.
References
Anselin, Luc (1988): Spatial Econometrics: Methods and Models, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, The Netherlands.
– (1992): SpaceStat Tutorial: A Workbook for Using SpceStat in the Analysis
of Spatial Data, National Centre for Geographical Information and Analysis, University of California.
– (1996): ‘The Moran Scatterplot as an ESDA Tool to Assess Local Instability in Spatial Association’ in M Fischer, H J D Scholten and Unwin (eds), Spatial Analytical Perspectives on GIS, Taylor and Francis, London, UK.
Anselin, Luc and A K Bera (1998): ‘Spatial Dependence in Spatial Regression Model with an Introduction to Spatial Econometrics’ in A Ullah and D E Giles (eds), Handbook of Applied Economic Statistics, Marcel Dekker, New York.
Casetti, E (1972): ‘Generating Models by Expansion Method: An Application to Geographic Research’, Geographical Analysis, 4, pp 81-91.
– (1997): ‘The Expansion Method, Mathematical Modelling, and Spatial Econometrics', International Regional Science Review, 20, pp 961-66. Dasgupta, D et al (2000): ‘Growth and Interstate Disparities in India’, Economic and Political Weekly, July 1, pp 2413-22.
Desarda, H M (1996): ‘The Other Side of Development: Maharashtra’s Backward Region’, Economic and Political Weekly, December 14, pp 3233-34.
Fischer, M M and C Stirbock (2004): ‘Regional Income Convergence in the Enlarged Europe, 1995-2000: A Spatial Perspective’, Discussion Paper No 04-42, ZEW (Centre for European Economic Research), Mannheim.
Fotheringham, A S, C Brunsdon and M Charlton (2002): Quantitative Geography: Perspectives on Spatial Data Analysis, Sage Publications, London.
Ghosh, B et al (1998): ‘Economic Growth and Regional Divergence in India, 1960-1995’, Economic and Political Weekly, June 27, pp 1623-30. Government of Maharashtra (1984): Report of the Fact Finding Committee
on Regional Imbalances, Planning Department, Mumbai.
Kurulkar, R P (2003): ‘Regional Disparities: Genesis and Solutions’ in B Mungekar (ed), The Economy of Maharashtra: Changing Structure and Emerging Issues, Dr Amdedkar Institute of Social and Economic Change, Mumbai, pp 209-33.
Lee, Sang Il (2004): ‘Spatial Analysis for the US Regional Convergence, 1969-1999: A Critical Appriasal of β-Convergence’, Journal of Korean Geographical Society, 39, 2, pp 212-28.
Lim, U (2003): ‘A Spatial Analysis of Regional Income Convergence’, Planning Forum, Vol 9, pp 66-80.
Marjit, S and S Mitra (1996): ‘Convergence in Regional Growth Rates: Indian Research Agenda’, Economic and Political Weekly, August 17, pp 2239-42.
Prabhu, K Sita and P C Sarker (1992): ‘Identification of Levels of Development of Districts in Maharashtra’,Economic and Political Weekly, September 5.
– (2003): ‘Imbalance in Regional Development’ in B Mungekar (ed), The Economy of Maharashtra: Changing Structure and Emerging Issues, Dr Ambedkar Institute of Social and Economic Change, Mumbai, pp 178-208.
Quah, Danny (1996): ‘Regional Convergence Clusters across Europe’, European Economic Review, 40, pp 951-58.
Raman, J (1996): ‘Convergence or Uneven Development: A Note on Regional Development in India’, The Indian Economic Journal, Vol 44, No 4, pp 135-44.
Rey, S J (2001): Spatial Analysis of Regional Income Inequality, Working Paper, Department of Geography, San Diego State University, San Diego.
Rey, Sergio J and B D Montouri (1999): ‘US Regional Convergence: A Spatial Econometric Perspective’, Regional Studies, 33, pp 143-56.
Shaban, A (2002): ‘Growth and Disparities of Incomes across Indian States’, Man and Development, September, pp 31-48.
Shaban, A and L M Bhole (1997): ‘Development and Disparities in Maharashtra: A Spatio-Temporal Analysis’, IndianJournal of Regional Science, March.
Upton, G J and B Fingleton (1985): Spatial Data Analysis by Example, Vol I: Point Pattern and Quantitative Data”, Wiley, New York.