Determinants of Expenditure on Education An Empirical Analysis Using State Level Data
Using a panel of 15 major states from India, this paper examines patterns and changes in the allocation of government funds for education, particularly higher education, over a span of two decades, before and after the introduction of the new economic policies. State real per capita income, with elasticity less than one, is found to significantly enhance educational expenditure at the aggregate, elementary, secondary and higher levels. Moreover, contrary to general perceptions, education expenditure at all levels has been significantly lower after liberalisation vis-à-vis the pre-economic reform era. This is particularly detrimental for the vulnerable sections of the population, i e, for females and backward social groups. It is evident that even after controlling for the economic reform process, privatisation exerts a negative significant impact on expenditure on higher education.
ANINDITA CHAKRABARTI, RAMA JOGLEKAR
I Introduction
T
The emphasis of the present paper is to examine the pattern and changes in the allocation of government funds for education (particularly higher education) over the span of two decades, before and after the introduction of the new economic policies. Our focus has been on analysing if there exists a structural break in pattern of expenditure pre- and post-economic reforms. The paper is divided into the following sections: Section II briefly reviews the education policies of the government. Patterns of education expenditure, including spending on various levels of education are elucidated in the Section III. It shows that there is considerable heterogeneity in expenditure pattern across states as well as for different educational levels. Section IV hence estimates the factors governing the interstate differential in educational spending (for different levels) using panel-specific econometric models. Finally, Section V concludes.
II Economic Reforms and Changing Educational Policies
The government of India launched a series of economic reform measures in July 1991. These measures included consistent and coordinated steps to reduce protection and liberalise controls over industry and foreign investment and increase competition in areas dominated by monolithic public sector enterprises. These policies had serious implications for social sector, as it led to drastic reduction in public subsidies and development expenditure, particularly on social services. The central government’s expenditure on social sector as a percentage of GDP declined from
1.43 per cent in the period 1985-90 to 1.41 per cent in the period 1991-97. Similarly, the state governments’ expenditure on social sector as a percentage of GDP decreased from 6.6 per cent in period 1985-90 to 6.2 per cent in 1990-95. The latter change is more important because state government’s share in total expenditure on social sector is very large.
It is obvious from above discussion that the resources for social services in general are declining after liberalisation. Juxtaposed with this is the fact that there exists considerable heterogeneity across the states and different population sub-groups in terms of educational performance. In one end of the spectrum is a state like Kerala with long-standing commitment towards improvement of social indicators, having a literacy rate as high as 90.86 per cent in 2001. On the other end of the spectrum lie the socalled BIMARU states of Bihar (47.00), Madhya Pradesh (63.74),
Economic and Political Weekly April 15, 2006 Rajasthan (60.41) and Uttar Pradesh (56.27) having a comparatively lower level of literacy. Even after more than 50 years since independence, India has not been able to resolve the gender gap present in educational indicators. The Census 2001 reveals a substantial difference in the male vis-à-vis female literacy rate at 75.96 and 54.28, respectively. The gap is larger for a state like Bihar where the male literacy rate is almost double of that of the female population as compared to Kerala with a male literacy rate of 94.20 and female literacy rate of 87.86 per cent. Similar discrepancy is also evident between those belonging to the scheduled caste and scheduled tribe category as compared to the general population. The Census 2001 data also highlights that the literacy rate for scheduled caste stands at 54.34 whereas that for scheduled tribe is 46.84 for all-India. The literacy rate for the general population is 65.38 in 2001.
In this section, we analyse how the educational policies, particularly pertaining to the higher education sector, have responded to these challenges. Education is financed through both governmental and private resources. However, a major commitment from government is required in financing education because of the positive externalities associated with it. The beneficial impact of education is not restricted to the individual alone but spills over to other members in the community, e g, there is welldocumented evidence of the beneficial impact of mother’s education on health of her children, increased training enhances productivity of not only an individual worker, but has a positive spillover effect on his/her co-workers, etc. Thus, education is widely considered as public good. It is also recognised that while considering the private returns to education, an individual does not take account of these externalities. Hence, provision of education may be suboptimal when left only to market forces and government intervention is required to provide an optimum level of education (taking into account the private as well as the social benefits).
However, when we come to each level of education, it is not clear whether to categorise it as public good or merit good. Elementary education is widely accepted as public good. On the other hand, in case of higher education, it is observed that while it is beneficial to the society, the private returns from higher education are more than social returns. Thus it is generally recommended that the burden of financing higher education should be shifted to private individuals. The liberalisation process feeds this line of thinking. This also gets reflected in our changing educational policies with greater emphasis on generation of additional resources through conventional and non-conventional measures. The national policy on education (NPE) (1986, 1992) as well as the recommendations made by the University Grant Commission (UGC) recognises the need for reducing the role of government in education sector and increasing the role of private sector, particularly in the sphere of higher education.
The NPE was adopted by the Parliament in May 1986. It was further updated in the year 1992. The NPE provides a comprehensive framework including a “plan of action”, assigning specific responsibilities for organising, implementing and financing its proposals. The policy reiterates the constitutional obligation of achieving universal education at the elementary stage through greater access and retention of children up to 14 years in age. It emphasises the need for substantial improvement in quality of education to enable all children to achieve essential levels of learning with greater priority to achieving higher enrolment of girls, SCs and STs. The primary importance (in case of secondary and elementary education) is on programmes aimed at the following: universalisation of elementary education, liquidating illiteracy, equality of access to educational opportunities to all sections throughout the country, enhancing the social relevance, quality and functional effectiveness of educational programmes, generating knowledge and developing technologies in scientific fields crucial to self-sustaining economic development. In this context, it is interesting to note that the policy does not elucidate the role of private institutions for elementary and secondary education.
However, in case of higher education the NPE clearly points out that the non-government sector can play a major role in funding higher education. Note, it is clearly stated in the document that “resources, to the extent possible, will be raised by mobilising donations, asking the beneficiary communities to maintain school buildings and supplies of some consumables, raising fees at the higher levels of education and effecting some savings by the efficient use of facilities” (National Policy on Education 1986, p 35).
Similar measures, in terms of generating resources for higher education through non-government sources, have also been echoed by the UGC. The UGC was formally established in November 1956 as a statutory body of the government of India through an act for the coordination, determination and maintenance of standards of university education in India. The UGC is the only grantgiving agency in the country, which has been vested with the dual responsibility of providing funds and that of coordination, determination and maintenance of standards in institutions of higher education. The UGC, in recent years has documented the need for greater role of private sector in financing higher education [UGC 2003]. Private financing of higher education is advocated on the following grounds: private returns on higher education far exceed the social returns; private sector benefits the most from higher education and public funding for higher education is insufficient to take up the challenging task of expansion and diversification of higher education system to meet the continuously growing demand. On one hand, it assures that providing quality higher education is the primary responsibility of the government and it will not withdraw from this responsibility. However, simultaneously it mentions that industrial houses may be encouraged to be partners with educational institutions directly for the development of human resources dedicated to their interests. The remaining portion of this chapter elucidates how far these changing policies have triggered off changes in actual expenditure pattern of the government on education.
III Pattern of Expenditure on Education
The total (state and central government) educational expenditure expressed as a percentage of GDP gives a good indication of priority given to education in the society. Mid-1980s, i e, the era when human resource development was given top-most priority, we see an increasing trend in educational expenditure as a per cent of GDP (see the figure).
However, with the advent of 1990s, the per cent of educational expenditure started declining. This was due to reform process and government’s efforts to cut down its expenses on social sector. Table 1 shows the growth rates of per capita real expenditure on education for three decades 1970s, 1980s and 1990s.
Expenditure
Figure: Expenditure on Education as Percentage of GDP
4.5 4
3.5 3
2.5 2
1.5 1
0.5

than on more productive items, e g, improvement of infrastructure, etc. This becomes evident when we explore the pattern of disbursement of funds under the revenue and capital heads (Table 2).
Expenditure on education can be on recurring items such as salary of teachers, administrative staff, etc, or it can be on capital infrastructure such as school building, libraries, equipment, etc. Expenditure on recurring items comes under the revenue account, whereas that on non-recurring items constitutes the capital account. As can be observed from Table 2, revenue expenditure constitutes major part, around 99 per cent, of total expenditure from 198081 to 1999-2000. On the other hand, the capital account forms
1971-721973-741975-761977-781979-801981-821983-841985-861987-881989-901991-921993-941995-961997-98
Source: Selected Educational Statistics, 2000-01.
negligible portion of total spending.
So far we have looked into the changing pattern of total public expenditure on education and growth rate pre- and postliberalisation. However, one of our primary interests is to analyse the devolution of funds for higher education vis-à-vis the other
The growth rate of per capita real expenditure has increased from
5.65 per cent in 1970s to 6.37 per cent in 1980s. Thereafter growth rate has decreased to 4.48 per cent in 1990s. The efforts of the government to withdraw from the education sector have resulted in the declining growth rate of per capita real expenditure on education.
Not only is the public funding on education declining over the last few years, but also the available resources are expended on meeting functional expenses, i e, payment to teachers, etc, rather
Table 1: Trends in Expenditure on Education
Period Average Per Coefficient of Growth Rate Capita Real Variation Expenditure
1971-72 to 1980-81 142.56 18.70 0.0565 1981-82 to 1990-91 243.24 19.50 0.0637 1991-92 to 1998-99 344.22 10.98 0.0408
Note: Growth rates are calculated with log-linear model. Source: Calculated from the Analysis of Budgeted Expenditure on Education.
Table 2: Revenue and Capital Expenditure on Education
Year Revenue Percentage Capital Percent-Total
Expendi-of Total Expendi-age Expenditure ture of Total ture (Rs Lakh) (Rs Lakh) (Rs Lakh)
1980-81 22730.40 99.22 177.83 0.78 22908.23 1985-86 50273.44 98.89 564.88 1.11 50838.32 1990-91 111666.54 98.84 1306.15 1.16 112972.68 1995-96 201467.27 99.17 1684.16 0.83 203151.44 1999-2000 374241.74 99.23 2917.60 0.77 377159.34
Source: Analysis of Budgeted Expenditure on Education (selected years).
levels of education. To address this issue, we have looked into the public spending on education at a more disaggregated level in Table 3. The greater priority to elementary and secondary education as compared to higher education is envisaged from the fact that as early as in 1974-75 approximately 45 per cent of total funds were allocated for elementary education, 30 per cent for secondary education and around 17 per cent for higher (inclusive of technical) education. The share of elementary, secondary and higher education has all declined marginally during reform period, but started picking up during mid-1990s. However, the pace of change has been more for elementary education as compared to higher education.
State-wise Expenditure on Education
As discussed in Section II, the state governments have borne the lion share of expenditure on social services. Education sector is not an exception. Note, after education was brought into the concurrent list from the state list through the 42nd Constitutional amendment, it was expected that the share of the central government would increase considerably. In reality, the share of the central government continues to be low and even in the secondhalf of 1990s, the central government’s share in total revenue expenditure on education has remained at around 14 per cent [Tilak 1995]. However, the proportion of state income allocated for meeting education expenses shows a far from uniform trend. This becomes clear when we explore the proportion of current net state domestic product (NSDP) spent on education for 15 major states over the decade prior to and after the introduction of new economic policies (refer to the Appendix). In 1990-91,
Table 3: Expenditure on Education by Levels
(Rs lakh)
Year | Elementary Education | Secondary Education | Higher Education | Technical Education | Total | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Actual | Per Cent | Actual | Per Cent | Actual | Per Cent | Actual | Per Cent | ||
of Total | of Total | of Total | of Total | ||||||
1974-75 | 71254.03 | 45.37 | 48385.38 | 30.81 | 20649.19 | 13.15 | 6632.62 | 4.22 | 157067 |
1980-81 | 153724.88 | 39.58 | 103690 | 26.70 | 48366.57 | 12.45 | 13695.17 | 3.53 | 388420 |
1985-86 | 344832.29 | 39.58 | 229387.25 | 26.33 | 104672.3 | 12.01 | 34541.6 | 3.96 | 871302 |
1990-91 | 795552.61 | 40.56 | 553111.31 | 28.20 | 231185.3 | 11.79 | 75301.36 | 3.84 | 1961585 |
1995-96 | 1521775.67 | 39.86 | 1034408.3 | 27.09 | 387133.3 | 10.14 | 129024.6 | 3.38 | 3817809 |
1996-97 | 1785044.06 | 40.66 | 1173572.6 | 26.74 | 428786.2 | 9.77 | 145000.8 | 3.30 | 4389648 |
1997-98 | 2039152.74 | 42.00 | 1326244.8 | 27.32 | 485913.8 | 10.01 | 162256.4 | 3.34 | 4855214 |
1998-99 (RE) | 2639203.4 | 42.86 | 1684374.7 | 27.35 | 631464.8 | 10.25 | 162256.4 | 2.63 | 6157891 |
1999-2000 (BE) | 2899719 | 37.63 | 1759661.2 | 22.84 | 799655 | 10.38 | 256419.3 | 3.33 | 7705630 |
Source: Calculated from the Analysis of Budgeted Expenditure on Education (various years).
Economic and Political Weekly April 15, 2006 the share of current NSDP allocated for education has declined compared to the corresponding proportion in 1985-86 for Andhra Pradesh, Haryana, Karnataka and Maharashtra. Prominent decline is observable in 1995-96. Comparing the percentage share of total education expenditure (to state income) for 1995-96 and 1990-91 we find that the requisite proportion has declined for all of the 15 major states except Assam and Rajasthan. This downward trend in the expenditure is somewhat reversed in the second-half of 1990s, where education sector has been given relatively more importance by state governments (refer to Appendix).
Moreover, there exists considerable heterogeneity amongst the states in terms of their aggregate spending on education at all levels. The share of public funds allocated for education has been consistently high for Kerala for the period of 1980-81 to 19992000 hovering between 5 and 6 per cent. The only exception is the year 1999-2000 when the share dropped marginally to 4.98. Surprisingly, the BIMARU states, namely, Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan and Uttar Pradesh did not display a distinctly different pattern from the other major states so far as percentage share of educational expenditure is concerned. In fact, in 1999-2000, Bihar (at 7.18 per cent) was the second-largest state in terms of proportion of fund allocated for education. However, this finding is not conclusive. As pointed out by Tilak (1995), if the state income is low (as in case of BIMARU states), then very low amount of spending on education will also give the impression that higher proportion of NSDP has been spent on education.
To get a clearer understanding of the disparity across states in their commitment towards education financing, we have also computed the coefficient of variation of real per capita expenditure on education (reported in Table 4).2 Coefficient of variation is showing a declining trend till the first-half of 1990s indicating that the interstate differences in real per capita spending has been going down. However, it has increased from 20.81 (for 1990-91 to 1994-95) to 27.95 (for the period 1995-96 to 1999-2000) in the period immediately after the inception of the new economic policies. Question is how far this rising disparity is reflected across different levels of education?
Hence, after studying the trend of overall expenditure pattern, let us look at the levelwise expenditure pattern for the 15 major states. We are particularly interested in the pattern of expenditure on higher education. Table 5 shows the mean per capita spending and coefficient of variation for four levels of education, namely, elementary, secondary, higher and technical education.3 It can be observed that the average per capita spending is substantially higher in case of elementary education compared to higher and technical education. This substantiates previous statistics revealing the preference of the state governments towards elementary education. Further, the coefficient of variation is substantially lower for elementary and secondary education as compared to higher and technical education. This represents the heterogeneity existing among the states in availability of facilities for higher and technical education. Further, it also indicates that in cases where states do not have enough funds to support all levels of education, they are concentrating on the provision of the elementary and secondary education and thus trying to achieve the goal underlined in the NPE (1986).
The above discussion on pattern of state government finances on education (both overall and for different levels) clearly shows that there exists considerable heterogeneity amongst states in terms of real per capita spending on education. Moreover, this imbalance is also observed within an individual state across the various levels of education. An important issue to address is: What determines how much a state is willing to spend on education of its populace? The next section of this paper tries to explore the factors governing states’ spending on education at a macro level.
IV Determinants of Public Expenditure: Panel Estimates
The primary interest is to estimate the magnitude and significance of variation in state real per capita income in determining the spending pattern of public education. In addition to this we shall also investigate the impact of liberalisation and privatisation on government spending after controlling for broad demographic and economic indicators at state level. Further, grants from centre also play a major role in financing state expenditure. Grants on an average have accounted for around 12 per cent of total state spending for the period 1980 to 2000 [Lalvani 2004]. The impact (if any!) of grants for expenditure on education per se is worth investigating.
Few studies, primarily based on developed nations, have analysed the factors governing public expenditure on education at local [Poterba 1996], state [ibid; She 2004; Verbina and Chowdury 2002] and national level [Strawczynski and Zeira 2003]. The variable of particular interest, i e, real per capita income is positively associated with expenditure on education. Moreover, in all of the above-mentioned studies, income elasticity was less than one indicating that education spending is inelastic to changes in income. No such consistent result emerged so far as the demographic indicators are concerned. A negative significant relationship was established between per child (or per capita) education spending and proportion of population in school-going age group (five to 17) using macro level data from the US [Poterba 1996; She 2004] and Russia [Verbina and Chowdury 2002]. However, no such significant relationship was found by Strawczynski and Zeira (2003) who unlike the other studies had
Table 4: Trends in State-wise Real Per Capita Expenditureon Education
Period Mean Coefficient of Variation
1980-81 to 1984-85 193.44 29.89 1985-86 to 1989-90 256.98 25.88 1990-91 to 1994-95 302.33 20.81 1995-96 to 1999-2000 364.29 27.95
Source: Calculated from Analysis of Budgeted Expenditure on Education.
Table 5: Trends in State-wise Real Per Capita Expenditure on Different Levels of Expenditure
Elementary Secondary Higher Technical Period Mean Coeff Mean Coeff Mean Coeff Mean Coeff of Var of Var of Var of Var
1980-81 to
1984-85 78.17 30.32 55.91 44.24 39.01 79.76 9.6 102.72 1985-86 to
1989-90 108.03 24.83 71.34 47.31 37.29 75.18 8.53 94.34 1990-91 to
1994-95 126.24 22.66 85.32 39.64 32.7 80.09 7.41 81.54 1995-96 to
1999-2000 155.83 31.16 106.64 49.94 32.34 80.14 7.79 109.27
Source: Calculated from Analysis of Budgeted Expenditure on Education, Coeff of Var denotes coefficient of variation.
looked into both public and private education expenditure in Israel. The other demographic control often incorporated is the proportion of population above the age group of 60. The underlying reason might be that such countries are often characterised by old age security/welfare programmes. Hence, this population subgroup may be competing with the available scarce public resources on one hand and also have no incentive to vote in favour of governments encouraging greater allocation of public funds on education. Estimated results matches with a priori expectations. For example, Poterba (1996) found that an increase in the fraction of elderly residents in a state is associated with a significant reduction in per child educational spending even after controlling for income, poverty and urbanisation. Further, the reduction is even larger when the elderly residents are predominantly from a different racial group than the school-age population. This inverse relationship between educational spending and aging of population is also supported by the other studies. This section is subdivided into the following sub-categories: Section 4.1 presents the model specification and data used in this study and Section 4.2 highlights the associated empirical results.
Model Specification and Data
The determinants of public education expenditure can be broadly classified as economic, demographic and social variables. India, on the other hand, had undergone different structural adjustments and policy reforms, namely, liberalisation and privatisation. Given this, the explanatory variables that we use to determine real per capita public expenditure on education is enlisted as follows: Economic variables: The existing literature highlights the significant role played by income in determining educational expenditure. Hence, the per capita NSDP (in 1993-94 prices) is incorporated to capture the economic well-being of the state. Both income and education have been expressed in logarithmic terms to enable us to compute the income elasticity. Given the federal structure, the state governments in India depend on the centre in terms of their revenue-generating capacity. Grants from the centre acts as one of the major elements in it. We have taken total grants from the centre, as percentage of NSDP, and expressed in natural logarithm, as another economic variable. These two variables, namely, income and grants, are expected to have a positive impact on education expenditure. Demographic variables: Changes in composition of schoolgoing population affect pattern of education spending. To control for this aspect, we have included the proportion of population belonging to the following age groups: five to nine (“Pop 5-9”), 10-14 (“Pop 10-14”), 15-19 (“Pop 15-19”) and 20-24 (“Pop 2024”). Micro-level studies (based on primary and secondary data) highlight the disadvantageous position of marginalised groups in educational achievement and household expenditure on education. In order to account for these factors, the proportion of population belonging to scheduled caste, scheduled tribe and sexratio4 are introduced. In addition to these variables we have also included the proportion of rural population (“rural”), which is largely dependent on the government for access to educational institutions. Policy variables: One of our primary objectives is to analyse whether there exists any significant change in public expenditure on education prior to and after the introduction of the new economic policies in 1991. The binary variable “reform” is created such that it takes the value of zero prior to policy changes and is one thereafter, i e, from 1991-92 to 1999-2000. Negative and significant coefficient of “reform” would indicate that economic reforms have adversely affected education spending. Recent years have witnessed rapid privatisation of the education sector in India, particularly the professional and technical courses. We have designed two variables, namely, “Engginst” and “Medinst”, to capture the impact of degree of privatisation on state financing of education. The variables measure the rate of privatisation in engineering and medical institutions. The engginst (medinst) takes the value one if the proportion of private engineering (medical) institutions in a state is higher than the national average and is zero otherwise. Given these explanatory variables the model is formulated as follows: Edu expit = ∂i + β1 * Incomeit + β2 * SCit + β3 * STit + β4*Ruralit
where i = 1,…..15 refers to states, t = 1,….20 indicates time, δi captures state-specific effect, and εit is the random error term varying across both cross section and time. Note, in addition to the explanatory variables enlisted above, we have also included a time trend. Two alternative model specifications have been tried. Firstly, a basic panel fixed effect model has been estimated to control for state-specific effects. Secondly, we have also presented the generalised least square estimates of the above model to account for heteroskedasticity and panel-specific autocorrelation among the error terms.5 Separate analysis has been carried out for aggregate education expenditure as well as that at individual level, i e, primary, secondary and higher.
The requisite model (equation (1)) has been estimated using annual data from 1980-81 to 1999-2000 for 15 major Indian states. Data on NSDP and grants is obtained from Reserve Bank of India’s publications; on education expenditure (total and individual level) from various issues of Analysis of Budgeted Expenditure on Education; on the demographic variables from the Census of India. In order to calculate the proportion of private medical and private engineering colleges, we have looked into lists of medical and engineering colleges available at websites of Medical Council of India and All-India Council of Technical Education, respectively. More detailed description of the data sources is provided in the Box. Table 6 outlines some descriptive statistics of the variables used in our panel regressions. The average public education expenditure across the 15 major states over a span of 1980-81 to 1999-2000 stood at 279.257 units – a meagre 3.8 per cent of the average real per capita NSDP. A lion’s share of the funds have been devoted towards elementary education (41.92 per cent) as compared to tertiary level education which attracted only 12.76 per cent of public funds devoted to education.
However, considerable discrepancy exists across the states with respect to their allocation for education. Average education expenditure, for all levels, was found to vary from 180.26 units in Uttar Pradesh to 370.88 units in Kerala. This explains the wide range reported for this variable (Table 6). A substantially high standard deviation is also prevalent in case of real per capita state domestic product. The emphasis on greater private participation in the field of higher education is evident from the fact that nearly 43 per cent of the engineering colleges across the 15 major states are under private management/ownership. The corresponding proportion for the medical colleges is comparatively lower at
Economic and Political Weekly April 15, 2006 14.6 per cent. Note, for both cases, the share of private colleges have shown a rising trend. The corresponding share for engineering discipline increased from 36.12 per cent in 1980-81 to
51.49 per cent in 1999-2000 and that for medical colleges increased from 12.07 per cent to 17.58 per cent in the interim period (not shown in Table 6).
Empirical Results
The results for the aggregate education expenditure is presented in Table 7 and that for expenditure at primary, secondary and higher level is reported in Tables 8, 9 and 10, respectively. The results are discussed under the broad classifications specified earlier. Economic variables: States with higher per capita income was found to spend more on education. This is evident from the positive significant coefficient of “income” for both the fixed effect as well as the generalised least square estimates (Table 7). The income elasticity at 0.242 and 0.219 respectively, is significantly less than one. This implies that aggregate expenditure on education is inelastic to changes in income. This is not surprising given that we have used only public expenditure on education. One would usually associate education expenditure being needbased and hence a necessity.
To get a better understanding of the impact of these socioeconomic level at a more disaggregated level, we have also looked into the determinants of education expenditure for elementary, secondary and higher education. “Income” has a significant positive impact on public expenditure on education irrespective of the level study. Moreover, income elasticity at each level, i e, elementary, secondary and tertiary education is found to be less than one. The result is surprising for higher education because although there is a change in classification with higher education no longer being considered as a purely public good but actual expenditure pattern reveals that the former is yet to be considered as a “luxury” item (Tables 8, 9 and 10). The magnitude of income elasticity is highest for secondary education (0.838 and 0.507), followed by higher (0.276 and 0.269) and elementary education, respectively (0.137).
Further, grants from centre induce a positive significant impact on public expenditure on education both at aggregate level and also individually at elementary, secondary and higher level (Tables 7 to 10). The effect is highest in case of secondary education followed by elementary education.6
Box
Table 6: Descriptive Statistics of Variables Used in the Panel Regressions
Variable Mean Std Dev Minimum Maximum
Education expenditure
in real per capita terms 279.257 96.875 75.946 727.760 Elementary education
expenditure in real
per capita terms 117.068 43.603 24.029 299.217 Secondary education
expenditure in real
per capita terms 79.800 42.046 1.498 288.321 Higher education expenditure
in real per capita terms 35.639 14.588 5.335 85.872 Real per capita NSDP 7217.511 2669.100 3330.858 14997.940 Proportion of private
engineering colleges 0.430 0.334 0.000 1.000 Proportion of private
medical colleges 0.146 0.222 0.000 0.810 Grants as proportion
of current NSDP 0.024 0.017 0.005 0.117 Percentage of SC population 15.901 5.664 6.820 28.800 Percentage of ST population 7.927 7.367 0.000 23.270 Percentage of rural population 75.074 8.309 57.111 90.120 Proportion of population in age
group of five to nine 0.129 0.018 0.055 0.160 Proportion of population
in age group of 10 to 14 0.120 0.012 0.047 0.141 Proportion of population
in age group of 15 to 19 0.096 0.010 0.034 0.118 Proportion of population
in age group of 20 to 24 0.089 0.01 0.031 0.107
Table 7: Determinants of Expenditure on Education
Fixed Effects Model Fixed Effects GLS Model Column (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Variable Coef Std Err P>|t| Coef Std Err P>|t|
Income 0.242 0.093 0.010 0.219 0.068 0.001 SC -0.031 0.017 0.079 -0.045 0.016 0.006 ST -0.020 0.013 0.129 -0.023 0.012 0.058 Rural 0.008 0.009 0.364 0.016 0.008 0.036 Grants 0.129 0.027 0.000 0.080 0.020 0.000 Pop 5-9 -1.441 1.757 0.413 0.856 1.474 0.561 Pop 10-14 -1.903 3.654 0.603 -10.007 4.250 0.019 Pop 15-19 6.494 5.504 0.239 14.300 6.382 0.025 Pop 20-24 -1.943 4.351 0.656 -3.451 4.159 0.407 Sexratio -0.004 0.001 0.001 -0.003 0.001 0.052 Engginst 0.014 0.022 0.532 0.008 0.021 0.696 Medinst -0.037 0.030 0.219 -0.017 0.029 0.554 Reform -0.162 0.026 0.000 -0.122 0.019 0.000 Time 0.049 0.004 0.000 0.048 0.003 0.000 Constant 7.587 1.661 0.000 5.729 1.835 0.002 R-square (within) 0.863 Wald
χ2(28) 3648.170
Prob > χ 2 0.000
Table 8: Determinants of Expenditure on Elementary Education
Fixed Effects Model | Fixed Effects GLS Model | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Column | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) |
Variable | Coef | Std Err | P>|t| | Coef | Std Err | P>|t| |
Income | -0.073 | 0.143 | 0.608 | 0.137 | 0.077 | 0.077 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
SC | -0.050 | 0.027 | 0.061 | -0.036 | 0.018 | 0.048 |
ST | -0.042 | 0.019 | 0.031 | -0.013 | 0.015 | 0.382 |
Rural | 0.008 | 0.013 | 0.538 | 0.029 | 0.010 | 0.002 |
Grants | 0.116 | 0.042 | 0.006 | 0.051 | 0.025 | 0.039 |
Pop 5-9 | -1.261 | 2.683 | 0.639 | -0.125 | 1.947 | 0.949 |
Pop 10-14 | -12.571 | 5.431 | 0.021 | -13.337 | 6.201 | 0.032 |
Pop 15-19 | 24.272 | 8.326 | 0.004 | 23.012 | 8.568 | 0.007 |
Pop 20-24 | -5.540 | 6.674 | 0.407 | -5.428 | 4.940 | 0.272 |
Sexratio | -0.004 | 0.002 | 0.052 | -0.003 | 0.002 | 0.107 |
Reform | -0.214 | 0.039 | 0.000 | -0.176 | 0.024 | 0.000 |
Time | 0.061 | 0.006 | 0.000 | 0.056 | 0.004 | 0.000 |
Constant | 9.213 | 2.523 | 0.000 | 4.200 | 2.188 | 0.055 |
R-square (within) | 0.749 | Wald | ||||
chi2(28) | 2060.720 | |||||
Prob > χ2 | 0.000 |
Demographic variables: Demographic variables, namely, SC, elementary and higher level. This is particularly discouraging ST, sexratio and rural, measure the effort of the government to in view of the fact that these social groups already lag behind extend educational facilities to deprived classes. States with a others in terms of their educational status. Similar results were higher proportion of scheduled caste population was found to also obtained for the scheduled tribe group. The variable ST is have a significantly lower expenditure on education at aggregate, generally negative and significant for aggregate and elementary education. The only case when it enters with a positive sign is
Table 9: Determinants of Expenditure on Secondary Education
when we consider the generalised least square estimates at the
Fixed Effects Model Fixed Effects GLS Model secondary stage. However, the impact is not significant.Column (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Is there a gender bias present for those states where the female
Variable Coef Std Err P>|t| Coef Std Err P>|t|
population is higher than their male counterpart? Our empirical Income 0.838 0.244 0.001 0.507 0.109 0.000 findings provide a substantial answer. The coefficient of sexratio
SC 0.017 0.045 0.703 0.012 0.026 0.659
enters with a negative significant coefficient in majority of the cases.
ST -0.047 0.033 0.153 0.011 0.044 0.808 Rural 0.007 0.023 0.756 -0.016 0.015 0.305 Although, this is a macro-level analysis it clearly highlights the Grants 0.146 0.071 0.041 0.075 0.027 0.006
need for government to put sustained effort in designing policies
Pop 5-9 -5.836 4.576 0.203 -0.850 3.565 0.812
Pop 10-14 4.835 9.264 0.602 4.574 6.028 0.448 and allocating resources targeted towards female population. The
Pop 15-19 1.460 14.203 0.918 8.518 9.072 0.348 coefficient of “rural” is in general positive and significant atPop 20-24 -5.840 11.385 0.608 -16.292 6.387 0.011
aggregate and elementary level. Dearth of private providers in
Sexratio -0.003 0.003 0.358 -0.005 0.003 0.085
Reform -0.094 0.067 0.163 -0.088 0.029 0.003 rural areas implies that the government has to assume a significant
Time 0.021 0.009 0.026 0.032 0.006 0.000 role in terms of provision of educational facilities in rural areas.Constant 0.266 4.304 0.951 6.392 3.039 0.035
This is partially borne out by our results. However, as expected
R-square (within) 0.484 Wald chi2
(28) 1334.030government commitment is more apparent at the elementary stage Prob > χ2 0.000 than at higher levels. The other variables in this category used to control for school/college-going age group is significantly
Table 10: Determinants of Expenditure on Higher and affecting educational expenditure in some cases. Technical Education
Policy variables: The variable reform displays a negative and Fixed Effects Model Fixed Effects GLS Model significant coefficient irrespective of level of education. These Column (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
results endorse the view that allocation of resources in favour
Variable Coef Std Err P>|t| Coef Std Err P>|t|
of social sectors, such as education, has significantly declined
Income 0.276 0.115 0.018 0.269 0.089 0.002 in the post-reform era. Our result corroborates the findings ofSC -0.037 0.021 0.086 -0.043 0.021 0.043
Rani (2004) and Tilak (2004). The latter documented the declin-
ST -0.014 0.016 0.381 -0.024 0.022 0.279 Rural 0.016 0.011 0.134 0.007 0.013 0.617 ing trend in allocation of resources for higher education in India,
Grants 0.071 0.034 0.038 0.041 0.025 0.101 particularly post-1991-92, and analysed the alternative mecha-
Pop 5-9 2.371 2.174 0.276 4.536 2.467 0.066
nisms designed for generation of revenue from non-government
Pop 10-14 7.356 4.521 0.105 7.250 4.486 0.106 Pop 15-19 -23.851 6.808 0.001 -24.713 7.297 0.001 sources for financing tertiary education. Pop 20-24 12.769 5.382 0.018 9.690 6.348 0.127 Binary variables, Engginst and Medinst incorporated to capture
Sexratio -0.010 0.002 0.000 -0.009 0.002 0.000
the degree of privatisation of higher education plays a significant
Engginst -0.044 0.028 0.111 -0.049 0.023 0.035 Medinst -0.067 0.037 0.070 0.009 0.037 0.800 role even after we control for reform. Negative and significant
Reform -0.160 0.032 0.000 -0.122 0.027 0.000 coefficient of these variables in case of higher and technical
Time 0.054 0.005 0.000 0.051 0.005 0.000
education clearly demonstrates the following: states where the
Constant 9.526 2.054 0.000 10.683 2.366 0.000 R-square (within) 0.778 Wald proportion of private colleges (for these courses) is higher than chi2(28) 2559.140
the national average has progressively withdrawn from provision
Prob > χ2 0.000
of higher education.
Appendix: State-wise Expenditure on Education
State Total Exp Current Exp as a Total Exp Current Exp as a Total Exp Current Exp as a Total Exp Current Exp as a Total Exp Current Exp as a
on Edu-NSDP Per Cent on Edu-NSDP Per Cent on Edu-NSDP Per Cent on Edu-NSDP Per Cent on Edu-NSDP Per Cent
cation (Rs Cr) of NSDP cation (Rs Cr) of NSDP cation (Rs Cr) of NSDP cation (Rs Cr) of NSDP cation (Rs Cr) of NSDP
(Rs Cr) (Rs Cr) (Rs Cr) (Rs Cr) (Rs Cr)
1980-81 1985-86 1990-91 1995-96 1999-2000
Andhra Pradesh 299.13 7754.87 3.86 704.41 14139.61 4.98 1238.31 31624.06 3.92 2214.26 71796.00 3.08 4403.48 112966.00 3.90 Assam 91.37 2365.04 3.86 226.11 5325.96 4.25 509.15 9775.07 5.21 1032.95 17170.00 6.02 2287.54 26273.00 8.71 Bihar 238.91 6945.30 3.44 591.47 13527.41 4.37 1404.41 24927.16 5.63 2087.4 38018.00 5.49 4597.14 64067.00 7.18 Gujarat 214.84 7109.99 3.02 521.42 13143.75 3.97 1051.18 26259.27 4.00 2096.79 61736.00 3.40 3853.78 90763.00 4.25 Haryana 84.05 3209.65 2.62 186.10 6127.13 3.04 390.69 12955.06 3.02 786.65 26166.00 3.01 1474.33 42922.00 3.43 Karnataka 200.67 6090.63 3.29 494.65 11139.08 4.44 878.66 22403.52 3.92 1921.95 50028.00 3.84 3088.09 85038.00 3.63 Kerala 241.48 4631.37 5.21 490.17 7878.05 6.22 880.85 14746.96 5.97 1819.09 35330.00 5.15 2837.31 56926.00 4.98 Madhya Pradesh 217.94 8396.19 2.60 496.11 14478.99 3.43 1275.18 31749.13 4.02 2256.94 56531.00 3.99 3495.36 90382.00 3.87 Maharashtra 461.42 15472.86 2.98 962.20 27007.86 3.56 2038.21 59325.05 3.44 4113.24 140730.00 2.92 10513.41 216664.00 4.85 Orissa 125.19 3527.51 3.55 207.61 6378.82 3.25 540.51 9901.21 5.46 1115.39 23822.00 4.68 1985.45 34223.00 5.80 Punjab 162.20 4371.64 3.71 275.06 8201.86 3.35 561.28 16446.95 3.41 751.56 34218.00 2.20 2341.61 54380.00 4.31 Rajasthan 160.70 4835.16 3.32 374.27 8987.12 4.16 909.45 21423.08 4.25 1845.82 41690.00 4.43 3266.40 69420.00 4.71 Tamil Nadu 285.48 8066.29 3.54 649.28 15289.97 4.25 1450.6 30926.38 4.69 2532.16 69719.00 3.63 4760.98 112741.00 4.22 Uttar Pradesh 380.85 15604.66 2.44 864.86 27472.99 3.15 2316.46 55121.93 4.20 3802.07 99792.00 3.81 6898.14 155273.00 4.44 West Bengal 271.99 10443.78 2.60 582.02 18957.52 3.07 1500.95 34290.08 4.38 2096.43 67136.00 3.12 5231.52 116899.00 4.48
Source: Calculated from the Analysis of Budgeted Expenditure on Education (various issues).
Economic and Political Weekly April 15, 2006
V Conclusion
In this paper, we have explored government financing of education in India over a span of 1980-81 to 1999-2000 across the 15 major states of the country using macro-level indicators. Our focus has been on analysing if there exists a structural break in pattern of expenditure pre- and post-economic reforms. Economic reform has certainly affected public expenditure on social sector in general and that on education sector in particular. Particular interest was to assess the income effect and that induced by liberalisation and commercialisation of higher education. The panel-based regressions are robust to both model specifications as well as to how we have defined educational expenditure. Income, with elasticity less than one, is found to significantly enhance educational expenditure at aggregate, elementary, secondary and higher level. Moreover, contrary to general perception, education expenditure at all levels has been significantly lower after liberalisation vis-à-vis pre-economic reform era. This is particularly detrimental for the vulnerable sections of the population, i e, for females and backward social groups. States with a higher proportion of population belonging to SC, ST and with higher female to male ratio are any case found to incur significantly lower expenditure on education. In addition to this, we find that even after controlling for the economic reform process, privatisation exerts a negative significant impact on higher education. In other words, government’s commitment towards meeting higher educational expenses is lower in those states where proportion of private engineering and medical colleges is relatively higher than the national average rate.

Email: anindita@tiss.edu
Notes
[This paper is a part of a research project entitled ‘Expenditure on Higher Education in India: Role Played by the Government and Household’ funded by the Board of Research Studies, Tata Institute of Social Sciences. The first author acknowledges their support.]
1 www.education.nic.in
2 Mean real capita expenditure on education is calculated by taking the average across the 15 major states for the requisite time periods.
3 Op cit.
4 Sex ratio is defined as proportion of female to male population.
5 See Greene (2003) for better exposition.
6 In addition to this we have also tried an alternative specification to ascertain whether there exists any flypaper effect in terms of education expenditure of the state governments. As pointed out by Lalvani (2004) “A test of the flypaper effect would show if grants exerted greater stimulatory effect on expenditures of state government than would an equivalent increase in income”. In this context, we have replaced total grants by “lump sum grants”. Lump sum grants are defined as total grants (given by the Finance and Planning Commissions) excluding grants given by the centre under the category “central sector and centrally-sponsored schemes” (see Lalvani 2004 for further details). The panel estimates reveal that lump sum grants does not induce any significant impact on public expenditure on education, either at aggregate level or for elementary, secondary and higher levels. Change of specification also does not alter the sign and level of significance of the other explanatory variables.
References
GoI (Selected Years): Analysis of Budgeted Expenditure on Education, Ministry of Human Resource Development.
Greene, W H (2003): Econometric Analysis, Pearson Education, New Delhi.
Lalvani, M (2004): ‘Flypaper Effect: Evidence from India’, Public Budgeting and Finance, 22(3), pp 67-88.
Poterba, J M (1996): ‘Demographic Structure and the Political Economy of Public Education’, NBER Working Paper Series No 5677, US.
Rani, G P (2004): ‘Economic Reforms and Financing Higher Education in India’, Indian Journal of Economics and Business, 3(1), pp 1-30.
She, C M (2004): ‘Determinants of Public School Expenditure in Elementary and Secondary Education’, mimeo, Indiana University.
Strawczynski, M and J Zeira (2003): ‘What Determines Education Expenditure in Israel?’, Israel Economic Review, 1, pp 11-33.
Tilak, J B G (1995): ‘Costs and Financing of Education in India: A Review of Issues’, Problems and Prospects, UNDP Research Project, Centre for Development Studies, Thiruvananthapuram, Kerala.
– (2004): ‘Public Subsidies in Education in India’, Economic and Political Weekly, pp 343-59. UGC (2003): ‘Higher Education in India: Issues, Concerns and New Directions’, mimeo, University Grant Commission, India.
Verbina, I and A Chowdury (2002): ‘What Determines Public Education Expenditures in a Transition Economy?’, United Nations University, Discussion Paper No 2002/60.