A+| A| A-
Article Title
Vulnerability of Consumption Growth
RAGHBENDRA JHA In the extant literature either income or consumption expenditures as measured over short periods of time (say a year) have been regarded as proxies for the material well-being of households. However, economists have long recognised that a household’s sense of well-being depends not just on its average income or expenditures, but also on the risks it faces. Further, the concept of poverty should not be visualised in a static context but should permit changes in the states of nature and uncertainty of consumption outcomes. These alter the vulnerability of the household and affect its sense of well-being. In this paper I provide estimates of the vulnerability of the consumption of rural households in India and compute average as well as certainty equivalent growth rates of consumption for representative (average) households for 14 major states: Andhra Pradesh, Assam, Bihar, Gujarat, Karnataka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. Mean real consumption for these states for the following National Sample Survey (NSS) rounds (years in parentheses) are analysed: 13th (1958), 14th (1959), 15th (1960), 16th (1961), 17th (1962), 18th (1964), 19th (1965), 20th (1966), 21st (1967), 22nd (1968), 23rd (1969), 24th (1970), 25th (1971), 27th (1973), 28th (1974), 32nd (1978), 38th (1984), 42nd (1987), 43rd (1988), 45th (1990), 46th (1991), 48th (1993), 50th (1994), 51st (1995), 52nd (1996) and 53rd (1997). Consumption figures for later rounds are not used in view of the well known difficulties of comparing consumption data for the 55th round with those of earlier rounds. The plan of the paper is as follows. Section I briefly surveys the empirical literature on vulnerability. I make a distinction between measures based on household level data and measures based on aggregate data when household level data is not usable. A measure of vulnerability based on such aggregate data is discussed in Section II. Section III discusses results on vulnerability for these 14 states. Section IV concludes. Extant literature has distinguished between three forms of vulnerability [Hoddinott and Quisumbing 2003a, b] – (i) vulnerability as expected poverty (VEP) or an ex ante measure of vulnerability; (ii) vulnerability as expected low utility (VEU) or an ex post measure of vulnerability; and (iii) Vulnerability as Uninsured Exposure to Risk (VER) VEP: VEP was first proposed by Chaudhuri et al (2002). Vulnerability is here considered as the probability that a household will fall into poverty in the future. Thus we have: Vit = Pr(ci,t+1 = z) ...(1) where Vit is the vulnerability of household i at time t. ci,t+1 is this household’s consumption at time t+1 and z is a poverty line. This is readily extended to the case where vulnerability rises with the length of the time horizon. Define Ri(n,z) as the probability of observing at least one spell of poverty for n periods and write: Ri(n,z) = 1 – [{(1 – (P(ci,t+1) < z,..., (1 – P(c,,t+n) < z)}] ...(2) This methodology then uses I(.) as an indicator equalling 1 if the condition is true and zero otherwise and considers household to be vulnerable if risk in n periods is greater than a threshold level of probability, p. Thus we have: Vi (p,n,z) = I {Rit (n,z) > p} ...(3) Empirically Chaudhuri et al (2002) estimate ex ante vulnerability by modelling a household consumption function for cross section data: ln ci = Xiβ + εi ...(4) where ci is per capita consumption expenditure for the ith household, Xi represents a bundle of observable household Economic and Political Weekly February 24, 2007 characteristics, β is a vector of parameters and εi is a zero-mean disturbance term that captures idiosyncratic shocks (household level shocks such as illness of main income earner) that contribute to differences in per capita consumption levels. The variance of the error term is defined as: σ2 φ.i = Xiθ ...(5) Estimation assumes that ci is normally distributed and estimates of β and θ are obtained using a three-step feasible generalised least squares (FGLS) methodology. Using these estimated values the expected log consumption and the variance of the log consumption for each household as follows: ^^ ^^ E[lnci X] =X β i i and V[lnc Xi] = Xi β i The probability that a household will be poor in the future (say at time t+1) is given by: ⎡ ^ ⎤
^^
⎢ln z − Xi β⎥ X )= Φv = Pr(ln c ln z i ⎢ ⎥ i ^ ⎢ ⎥ X θ ⎣ This can be estimated using cross section data. However, it is sensitive to distributive assumptions about the error term. Further the accuracy of the estimates depends upon whether the distribution of consumption across households, given a set of characteristics at a given point in time, is an accurate representation of the time-series variation of the consumption of the households. VEU: Ligon and Schechter (2003) define the vulnerability of a typical household as the difference between the utility from a certainty equivalent consumption (z) sufficient to ensure that cethe household is not regarded as vulnerable and the expected value of the actual utility of the household from its (risky) stream of consumption. They then define vulnerability as the sum of three components: poverty (on average), aggregate risk and idiosyncratic risk. Minimisation of vulnerability is then tantamount to maximising expected utility. Consumption of a household ci, has a distribution over different states of the world. Then vulnerability is defined as: Vi = Uh(z)– EUi(ci) cewhere Uh is a weakly concave, strictly increasing function. This can be rewritten as: Vi = [Ui(z)– Ui(Eci)] + [Ui(Eci)– EUi(ci)]. ceThe first term is a measure of poverty – the difference between utility from zand actual consumption, c. The second term is ce a measure of the risk that the household faces. As Ligon and Schechter (2003) show, this term can be split up into a measure of aggregate risk and a measure of idiosyncratic risk. Thus we cane write: Vi =[Ui(z)– U(Eci)] (poverty) ce − x)]}(Aggregate risk)+{Ui(Eci) − EUi[E(ci − +{EUi[E(ci x)] − EUi(ci)} (Idiosyncratic risk) VER: When risks are not managed effectively shocks result in drops in consumption and hence welfare losses. To this extent what matters is the uninsured exposure to risk. VER is an ex post measure of vulnerability. To get an estimable form of such vulnerability consider a household, h, living in village v at time t. Let Δ ln chtv be the rate of growth of consumption per capita of this household between t-1 and t. Now write S(i)tv as the aggregate shock and S(i)htv as the idiosyncratic shock. Also write D as a set of binary variables identifying each village and X vas a vector of household characteristics. The equation to be estimated for VER can be written as: Δ ln citv = ∑λiSiv + ∑βiSitv + ∑δ(Dv) +δvXitv + Δεitv ii i Of particular interest are the parameters λ and β as they capture the effects of aggregate and idiosyncratic shocks, respectively. Empirically as Gaiha and Imai (2004) argue, this can be more difficult than identifying a poor household. Vulnerability depends on the severity of shocks – both idiosyncratic as well as general. Typically households are better able to cope with idiosyncratic shocks as opposed to general shocks. Within the context of measurement poverty, as Gaiha and Imai argue, it is important to identify those households that become chronically poor as a result of such general shocks. This measurement necessarily involves the use of household level data. In this vein Gaiha and Imai (2006) in a seminal analysis assess the vulnerability of rural households in the semi-arid tropics of south India. They employ both ex ante and ex post measures of vulnerability and show that idiosyncratic risks account for the largest share (37 per cent), followed by poverty (35 per cent) and aggregate risks (22 per cent). Thus despite some risk sharing at the village level, the rural population, particularly the landless, less educated, members of socially disadvantaged groups and small farmers are vulnerable to idiosyncratic risks. Such risks force them to reduce consumption thus aggravating poverty and vulnerability. The ICRISAT data set used by Gaiha and Imai is unusual in that it traces the same households over a period of time. In the case of the NSS, however, this is not the case. Nevertheless, the NSS data sets have the advantages that they cover the whole country and not just the semi-arid parts as the ICRISAT data set does and that the NSS rounds (especially the quinquennial rounds) survey a much larger number of households than the ICRISAT data set. In the case of the NSS data set, then, two routes are open to assessing vulnerability of consumption growth. One could use the cross section techniques of Chaudhuri et al (2002). Doing this will, however, be subject to the criticism of this technique listed above. Also it would not be straightforward to arrive at comparable measures of the evolution of vulnerability over time. Alternatively, one can use a technique that focuses on the aggregate data. This ignores distributional considerations2 but has the advantage that it provides consistent measures of vulnerability that are comparable over time. The present paper uses the latter approach.3 This is due to Auffret (2002, 2003). He provides a framework to compute vulnerability using aggregate data. This methodology essentially involves computation of a rate of growth of real consumption with no uncertainty that would give a representative consumer the same utility as the observed (uncertain) consumption growth. The consumption of a representative individual is equated with per capita consumption and Economic and Political Weekly February 24, 2007 it is assumed that this (uncertain) aggregate per capita consumption follows a geometric Brownian motion with drift represented by dc =μdt +σdZ where dZ is a standard Brownian motion with c expectation and variance equal to 0 and dt, respectively. The expected instantaneous per capita consumption growth is μ and σ2 is the variance with σ as the standard deviation. The standard deviation is often referred to as the volatility of real per capita consumption. Using Ito’s Lemma, it can be shown that ⎛ 12 ⎞ d(logc ) =⎜μ− σ⎟.dt +σ.dZ. Hence ⎝ 2 ⎠ ⎡⎛ 1 ⎞⎤ ct= c0 exp⎢⎜μ− σ2 ⎟+σ[Z(t +1) − Z(t)]⎥ and 2 ⎣⎝⎠ ⎦ ⎛ ct+1 ⎞⎛ 12 ⎞ log⎜⎜ ⎟⎟=⎜μ− σ ⎟+σ[Z(t +1) − Z(t)].Hence the variance ct ⎝ 2 ⎠ ⎝⎠ of per capita consumption growth and the expected instantaneous consumption growth are respectively given by ⎡⎛⎞⎤ ⎡⎛ c ⎞⎤ 2 ct+1 t+1 12 σ= var⎢log⎜⎜ ⎟⎟⎥ and μ= E⎢log⎜⎜ ⎟⎟⎥ + σ where var ⎢⎝ ct ⎠⎥ ⎢⎝ ct ⎠⎥⎦ 2 ⎣⎦ ⎣ and E refer to unconditional variance and expectation. Auffret (2002) shows that this consumption process has the advantage of not violating the assumption of non-negative consumption and can be derived as the optimal outcome in a general equilibrium model with constant returns to scale technology defined by dY/K = a dt + s dZ where K represents the stock of capital, dY is the instantaneous output and the technological coefficients {a,s} are exogenously specified constants with s0. Following Auffet assume that (i) Individuals have time-separable expected utility function with 1−ρ c −1 constant risk-aversion preferences given by u(c) = where 1−ρ ρ 0 and ρ≠ 1 is the coefficient of relative risk aversion or u(c) = log(c), the limiting case when ρ =1. (ii) Per capita consumption follows a geometric Brownian motion with drift represented by dc =μdt +σdZ . c (iii) The rate of time preference is β 0. Per capita consumption at any time t is given by ⎡⎛ 1 ⎞ ⎤ ct = c0 exp⎢⎜μ− σ2 ⎟+σ[Z(t +1) − Z(t)]⎥. Expected utility is 2 ⎣⎝⎠ ⎦ ∞ ⎡⎤ 2 −βt V(c0,μ,σ ,ρ) = E0 ⎢∫ u(t)e dt⎥ which can be rewritten as: ⎣0 ⎦ 1−ρ c1 1 V(c,μ,σ2,ρ) = 0 − the same 1 ⎛ 12 ⎞β(1−ρ) −ρ β+ (ρ−1)⎜μ− ρσ⎟ ⎝ 2 ⎠ expected utility is obtained when per capita consumption follows the deterministic process represented by dc ⎛ 12 ⎞ 12 =⎜μ− ρσ ⎟dt =μ where μ0 =μ− 2 ρσ . μ0 is then de c ⎝ 2 ⎠ 0 fined as the certainty-equivalent consumption growth. The extant approach implicitly assumes that ρ = 0, thereby using actual rate of growth as a measure of average welfare changes. Auffet argues that a more plausible value is ρ = 4. A simple plot of the growth of per capita consumption in these 14 states (not reported here) over this time reveals that there has State (Period) Real Per Capita Consumption Certainty (Constant Rupees) Equivalent Growth Standard Skewness Kurtosis Consumptiona (Per Cent Deviation Growth Per Year) x100 (Per Cent μ Per Year) μ0 AP 1960-69 AP 1970-78 AP 1984-90 AP 1991-97 Assam 1960-69 Assam 1970-78 Assam 1984-90 Assam 1991-97 Bihar 1960-69 Bihar 1970-78 Bihar 1984-90 Bihar 1991-97 Gujarat 1960-69 Gujarat 1970-78 Gujarat 1984-90 Gujarat 1991-97 KNTK 1960-69 KNTK 1970-78 KNTK 1984-90 KNTK 1991-97 KRL 1960-69 KRL 1970-78 KRL 1984-90 KRL 1991-97 MP 1960-69 MP 1970-78 MP 1984-90 MP 1991-97 MH 1960-69 MH 1970-78 MH 1984-90 MH 1991-97 OR 1960-69 OR 1970-78 OR 1984-90 OR 1991-97 PU 1960-69 PU 1970-78 PU 1984-90 PU 1991-97 RJ 1960-69 RJ 1970-78 RJ 1984-90 RJ 1991-97 TN 1960-69 TN 1970-78 TN 1984-90 TN 1991-97 UP 1960-69 UP 1970-78 UP 1984-90 UP 1991-97 WB 1960-69 WB 1970-78 WB 1984-90 WB 1991-97 Note: a: In line with Auffret (2003) I assume that ρ=4, which is consistent with empirical evidence. Source: Author’s computation based on data from NSS. Economic and Political Weekly February 24, 2007 been much variability of pre capita consumption growth in each of these 14 states. The table displays basic statistics on real per capita consumption growth in these 14 states (mean growth rate, standard deviation, skewness and kurtosis) along with the computed certainty equivalent growth rates. Results are reported for decades or as close to decades as the data will permit. Four periods are chosen (i) 1960-69; (ii) 1970-78; (iii) 1984-90; and (iv) 1991-97. The table provides interesting information about the distribution of the growth of real per capita consumption in these states. In Andhra Pradesh real per capita consumption growth was high and rising over the period but so was the standard deviation of consumption growth so that certainty equivalent consumption growth during 1991-97 was virtually the same as that between 1970 and 1978. Except for 1984-90 Assam had low consumption growth. The standard deviation of consumption was such that except for 1984-90 certainty equivalent consumption growth was negative. Bihar, too, had low consumption growth with high standard deviations – particularly during 1960-69 and 1984-90. Certainty equivalent consumption growth was positive (but small in magnitude) only for 1970-78 and 1984-90. The growth of real per capita consumption in Gujarat was low during 1960-69 but picked up in the latter two periods, dropping off again in 1991-97. Standard deviations was moderately high but not rising with the result that except for 1960-69 certainty equivalent consumption growth has been positive. Karnataka’s growth rates have fluctuated considerably. They were negative during 1960-69 and 1984-90 but strongly positive in the other two time periods. The standard deviation fell and then rose. Certainty equivalent consumption growth was positive in 1970-78 and 1991-97. Kerala had low growth rates in the first and last periods. However, the standard deviation in the last period was low so that certainty equivalent consumption growth was negative only during 1960-69. MP recorded buoyant growth with low standard deviation during 1984-90. Its consumption growth rate was negative during 1960-69 and 1991-97 and marginally positive during 1970-78. Certainty equivalent consumption growth was negative during 1960-69 and 1991-97. Consumption growth was high in Maharashtra only during 1970-78, although it was positive for all four periods. 1970-78 was the only period for which certainty equivalent consumption growth was positive. Consumption grew rapidly in Orissa during 1984-90 and less rapidly during 1970-78. In the other two periods both actual consumption growth and certainty equivalent consumption growth were negative. Punjab also appears to have been subject to considerable consumption shocks. Both actual and certainty equivalent consumption growth were negative during 1960-69. Consumption growth was quite rapid during 1970-78 and 1984-90 during the heyday of the green revolution in that state but slackened off during 1991-97. Certainty equivalent consumption growth was positive during 1970-78, 1984-90 and 1991-97. Rajasthan had negative certainty equivalent consumption growth in all four periods despite the fact that actual consumption grew rapidly during 1970-78. Tamil Nadu’s growth rate rose steadily from 1960-69 before dropping off again during 1991-97. Except for 1960-69 certainty equivalent consumption growth has been Economic and Political Weekly February 24, 2007 positive. Except for 1984-90 UP has had low consumption growth. Except for 1984-90 certainty equivalent consumption growth has been negative. West Bengal enjoyed high consumption growth during 1970-78 and 1984-90. In the other two periods both actual consumption growth and certainty equivalent consumption growth were negative. Some of the observed patterns of actual and certainty equivalent consumption growth could be the result of the way the periods are constructed or because data from some of the NSS rounds (26th, 29th, 30th, 31st, 33rd, 34th, 35th, 36th, 37th, 39th, 40th, 41st, 44th, 47th and 49th) have not been used. However, the basic point that in view of fluctuations in consumption growth certainty equivalent consumption growth has been lower than observed consumption growth in rural India has been made. The pattern of consumption growth has shown hints of convergence. A regression of the average growth in actual consumption growth over the period 1958-97 against the logs of real consumption per capita in these states has a strong negative coefficient, thus indicating that states that had relatively high per capita real consumption in 1958 grew less rapidly than states with low per capita real consumption. When this regression was run with average certainty equivalent growth rates and logs of real per capita consumption in 1958 the coefficient was again strongly negative. Hence, in both cases, there appears to be some convergence. However, in view of the volatility of the consumption growth figures, this result could change if a different base year was chosen. Whereas much has been written about the evolution of real SGDP of Indian states, relatively little has been said about the behaviour of consumption. In fact, consumption has, more often than not, been analysed only in the aggregate in macroeconomic analysis. What is undeniable, however, is that average consumption, under relatively small changes in distribution, is linked to living standards and is, therefore, a welfare measure of critical importance. This paper has emphasised the implications of one aspect of consumption – its variability – in India’s rural sectors. It has argued that the high variability of consumption in the rural sector has led to certainty equivalent consumption growth being substantially lower than actual growth in many cases. Thus, welfare in India’s rural sector has been rising more slowly than would be indicated by the movement in actual consumption growth or state GDP per capita growth. Such variability and the inability of rural consumers to smoothen consumption over time, partly due to poor or non-existent insurance facilities, have led to a situation where certainty equivalent consumption growth has been sluggish. This should be a matter of immense policy significance. Indeed it can be argued that the analysis in this paper is only suggestive, since the estimation has been done at the relatively aggregative level of individual states and data for recent time periods are not used. It would be useful to assess fluctuations in the average rates of growth at more disaggregated levels – say agro-climatic zones or even at the district or block level. This would blunt genuine concern that analysing consumption data at the level of states obfuscates distributional issues. Furthermore, the disaggregated analysis could be conducted using data collected involving consistent methodology post-1999-2000. This analysis also has implications for the analysis of poverty. A statistical measure of poverty based on consumption or income at different points of time ignores the fact that variability of its consumption has an impact on the utility of the household. If a utility interpretation were given to the standard measures of poverty, it would have to be that such standard measures of poverty implicitly assume that the consumption stream is certain. It could be that a household that is regarded as having risen from below the poverty line to above it during any time period may actually have experienced considerable variations in consumption during this period, so that in terms of certainty equivalent consumption the household may still be below the poverty line. Assessing vulnerability is, therefore, fundamental to any assessment of human welfare and an approach that focuses only on observed consumption at a point in time without reference to the history of such consumption, is subject to the risk of misrepresenting vulnerability. Email: r.jha@anu.edu.au [Thanks are due to Raghav Gaiha for introducing me to this literature and for helpful comments. The views expressed here are those of the author alone.] 1 For an early and insightful analysis of the impact of macroeconomic risks on poverty in India see Datt and Ravallion (1997). 2 It can be argued that ignoring distributional considerations is not a serious drawback in view of the relative stability of the Gini coefficient of consumption in these 14 states over these rounds of the NSS [Datt and Ravallion 2002; Jha 2004]. 3 Estimation for NSS data sets along the lines of the cross section analysis conducted by Chaudhuri et al (2002) is a complementary analysis which can, fruitfully, be the subject of future research. Auffret, P (2002): ‘The Importance of Financial and Insurance Market Integration in the Context of High Consumption Volatility in CGCED Countries’, World Bank, Washington DC. – (2003): ‘High Consumption Volatility: The Impact of Natural Disasters?’, Policy Research Working Paper 2962, World Bank. Chaudhuri, S, J Jalan and A Suryahadi (2002): ‘Assessing Household Vulnerability to Poverty from Cross Sectional Data: A Methodology and Estimates from Indonesia’, Discussion Paper, Columbia University. Datt, G and M Ravallion (1997): ‘Macroeconomic Crisis and Poverty Monitoring’, Review of Development Economics, 1(2); 135-52. Jha, R (2004): ‘Reducing Poverty and Inequality in India: Has Liberalisation Helped?’ in G A Cornia (ed), Inequality, Growth and Poverty in an Era of Liberalisation and Globalisation, Oxford University Press, New York, pp 297-326. Ligon, E and L Schechter (2003): ‘Measuring Vulnerability’, Economic Journal, 113(1): 95-102. Economic and Political Weekly February 24, 2007 Vulnerability of Consumption Growth
in Rural India
The fragility of livelihoods and hence the vulnerability of consumption growth due to aggregate shocks in the Indian rural sector have been highlighted recently. However, as yet there exist no estimates of the vulnerability of consumption growth in rural India. This paper attempts to fill this lacuna by providing “certainty equivalent growth of consumption” in 14 major states of India over the period 1958-97, corresponding to NSS rounds 13th to 53rd. It is shown that certainty equivalent growth of consumption in rural India has been much lower than average real per capita consumption growth – indeed, in some cases, it has been negative. This points to the poor performance of consumer-perceived average welfare in India’s rural sector and should be a matter of urgent policy concern.
I
I
Empirical Literature on Vulnerability
II
Measure of Vulnerability:
Present Paper’s Approach
Defining and Measuring Certainty –
Equivalent Consumption Growth
III
Results on Vulnerability of Consumption
in Rural India
Table: Real Per Capita Consumption Statistics
0.62
4.99
-0.99
-0.08
0.12
4.26
8.17
-0.87
0.43
2.93
4.18
6.73
0.47
1.02
3.27
5.38
11.10
-0.07
-1.05
2.92
-3.32
6.20
-0.17
-0.37
-4.09
0.36
6.76
1.56
2.32
-0.55
5.69
6.56
1.68
3.09
4.83
-1.76
8.24
-0.63
1.34
-3.12
1.30
23.09
0.90
1.49
-9.37
0.75
3.13
-0.06
-1.49
0.55
2.26
9.33
1.81
3.26
0.52
-0.42
3.81
-1.72
3.50
-0.71
0.55
5.57
0.89
-0.06
-0.07
2.44
7.11
-0.06
-1.35
1.43
2.79
7.30
-0.05
-0.84
1.73
1.54
6.54
0.28
0.61
0.68
-1.87
13.24
-0.16
-0.26
-5.38
3.81
4.56
0.37
-2.34
3.39
-0.74
7.22
-0.50
-1.58
-1.78
3.28
11.59
0.45
0.73
0.59
1.03
10.17
-0.52
-0.68
-1.04
5.00
13.25
-1.49
3.10
1.48
2.97
9.59
-0.44
-0.60
1.13
1.00
2.09
-0.46
0.82
0.92
-1.71
10.28
-0.04
0.15
-3.82
1.19
2.59
0.90
0.71
1.06
5.76
3.39
-0.10
-4.70
5.53
-1.27
3.85
-0.56
0.99
-1.57
0.46
8.22
-1.87
3.55
-0.89
6.17
12.05
-0.08
-0.32
3.26
0.33
6.06
-0.79
1.84
-0.41
0.85
11.26
-0.59
2.05
-1.69
-1.41
10.22
0.42
-1.13
-3.50
2.38
9.73
0.80
0.76
0.48
6.46
8.03
0.00
-2.83
5.17
-0.96
6.47
0.24
1.53
-1.80
-0.09
11.57
0.77
0.49
-2.77
4.89
12.97
0.32
-0.06
1.56
4.31
2.36
-0.05
-5.03
4.20
3.09
4.92
-1.45
2.33
2.61
-1.12
8.58
-0.36
2.98
-2.59
9.39
22.72
2.01
4.18
-0.93
-2.96
13.16
0.15
1.01
-6.42
-1.91
4.65
-1.96
4.12
-2.34
0.14
8.56
0.15
0.18
-1.33
3.61
4.67
0.56
-2.58
3.17
3.01
4.94
0.86
1.51
2.52
1.82
3.97
1.10
0.13
1.50
0.50
14.60
0.19
-0.67
-3.76
1.87
13.09
0.75
-1.65
-1.56
3.57
10.48
-0.23
-3.41
1.37
-1.49
5.79
-1.53
2.39
-2.16
-2.51
10.68
1.45
1.64
-4.79
4.15
7.29
-0.32
-2.88
3.09
7.59
5.12
0.01
-1.74
7.07
-0.02
4.76
-1.50
2.67
-0.47
m
IV
Conclusions
Notes
References